This site uses cookies to store information on your computer. Some are essential to make our site work; others help us improve the user experience. By using the site, you consent to the placement of these cookies. Read our  privacy policy  to learn more.

  • CAMPUS TO CLIENTS

Accounting for Income Tax: A Student Research Project

  • Individual Income Taxation
  • Specialized Issues

In a research project in the Master of Accountancy Program at the University of North Carolina at Charlotte, students completed an in-depth study of the consolidated financial statements and accompanying footnotes of a publicly traded, multinational company based in the southeastern United States. This project is easily adaptable for use in both undergraduate and graduate accounting and tax programs.

Background of ASC Topic 740

Standards for accounting for income taxes were previously provided in FASB Statement No. 109, Accounting for Income Taxes , which was issued in 1992. This statement was codified mostly in FASB Accounting Standards Codification (ASC) Topic 740, Income Taxes (Topic 740). When the statement was issued, FASB recognized that "income taxes must be computed for complex business transactions within the context of voluminous, complicated, and constantly changing tax laws, rules, and regulations" ( ¶ 69).

The Financial Accounting Foundation issued its Post-Implementation Review Report on the standard in 2013, in which the review team found that "complying with Statement 109 is more difficult today than when the standard was issued because of increased complexities resulting from changes in the economic environment and the tax laws as well as increased operations by U.S. companies in many different foreign jurisdictions."

The review team found preparers and practitioners had difficulties in applying the standard in the following areas: (1) accounting for valuation allowances and (2) computing deferred tax liabilities and deferred tax assets. Preparers and practitioners also face operational challenges in the following areas: (1) intraperiod tax allocations; (2) accounting for intercompany transfers of assets; and (3) situations in which a deferred tax liability is not recognized for earnings determined to be indefinitely reinvested in foreign subsidiaries. The review team also found that investors who participated in the study had difficulty understanding income tax information provided in the financial statements.

In 2006, FASB issued Interpretation No. (FIN) 48, Accounting for Uncertainty in Income Taxes , which clarified accounting for uncertainty in recognition of income taxes in financial statements. FIN 48 (which is also incorporated mostly into Topic 740) provided guidance on measuring and reporting the benefits of tax positions taken or expected to be taken on tax returns. However, companies continue to face uncertainty in estimating the probability that a tax position would be sustained on audit. This estimate is necessary because a company may recognize only the amount of a benefit from a tax position that has more than a 50% likelihood of being sustained on examination by the taxing authority in its financial state ments.

Purpose of the Student Project

The research project was designed to give students a better understanding of the application of Topic 740 in the real world. Students often find this subject challenging, in part because of the complexities described above. Another reason students fail to fully understand this area of accounting is their lack of experience in reading and analyzing published financial statements, particularly those segments covering accounting principles and reporting practices for income tax expense and related accounts.

Accounting students need to gain an awareness of the variety and complexity of business transactions to succeed in understanding how businesses measure and report income tax expense and related accounts. The study of financial statements and related footnotes in an annual report provides a path for students to gain this awareness and an understanding of Topic 740.

Nature of the Project

The project was an independent study in which graduate students committed to study a published annual report of a designated company for one semester. The students' objective was to learn as much as possible about current financial reporting practices in audited financial statements prepared in accordance with GAAP. In that context, students focused on all significant accounts involving application of Topic 740's rules. For each account, the students conducted research on the applicable U.S. tax rules and consulted Topic 740 to determine the applicable GAAP rules.

The instructor met with the students and discussed the nature of the assignment, as well as the sequence of research steps. The students' first step was to read the annual report to learn about the company's operations and financial statements. Then the students began identifying balance sheet and income statement accounts that involve book-tax differences. The instructor and students had several meetings and exchanged emails about the preliminary findings and the identification of the most significant accounts requiring analysis in the student reports.

A master of accountancy student may have (or may acquire) an internship or full-time job with a company under study, or with the accounting firm that provides tax and/or audit services for the company. The students were instructed not to obtain any supplementary information from the company or its accounting firm because that could result in disclosure of confidential information. For this project, the research sources were limited to the published annual report and other documents filed with the SEC. This restriction is consistent with the intended focus of the research project.

Research Procedure

As noted earlier, the first step was to identify accounts that involve (1) one set of rules for computing book income and (2) a different set of rules for computing taxable income on a U.S. corporate income tax return. The students conducted research to determine applicable GAAP rules and tax rules the company used for those accounts. Resulting differences in book income and taxable income for the current period were identified as either permanent or temporary differences. Deferred tax assets and deferred tax liabilities resulting from temporary differences in the book and tax basis of assets and liabilities were described. Also identified were deferred tax asset accounts associated with losses and credits carried forward and used in future periods.

Next, the students addressed issues related to (1) uncertainties whether deferred tax assets will be realized and whether valuation accounts may be needed and (2) uncertainties whether tax positions will be sustained upon audit, which may require the accrual of additional tax liabilities. Finally, the students examined the procedure for computing both the income tax provision and the effective income tax rate.

The company in this study had sales of about $255 million in its latest fiscal year. In each of the last three years, the company had net income before tax expense (benefit) in the range of $14 million to $15 million. The company's federal corporate statutory income tax rate was 34% in each of the last three years, while the company's effective income tax rate ranged from negative 7.3% to positive 7.9% during that period.

Companies report effective tax rates that are lower than the statutory rates as a result of: (1) earning income that is not subject to income tax, such as municipal bond interest income; (2) earning income in a foreign country where income tax rates are lower than the U.S. statutory income tax rate; (3) reducing the valuation account balance for deferred tax assets; and (4) other factors. The company in this study reduced the effective tax rate by 26% for the latest fiscal year as a result of reducing the balance in the valuation account for deferred tax assets. A study by the U.S. Government Accountability Office found that about 33% of large corporations had effective tax rates of 10% or less ( U.S. Multinational Corporations: Effective Tax Rates Are Correlated With Where Income Is Reported , Rep't No. GAO-08-950 (8/12/08)).

The balance sheet for the company contains seven asset and liability accounts related to income tax. The footnotes indicate the company had gross deferred tax assets of approximately $30 million and deferred tax liabilities of about $5 million. Operating loss carryforwards accounted for about 80% of the total amount of deferred tax assets. A valuation allowance of $12 million was reported for the deferred tax assets. Unrecognized tax benefits are related to 27% of the gross deferred tax assets. Significant deferred tax assets and deferred tax liability accounts are listed in the exhibit .

Adapting Project for Use as a Regular Course Assignment

Using this project in a stand-alone course requires students to commit more time than is usually required for an extra project in a standard tax course. However, the instructor has modified the project substantially to use it in the corporate tax course and in other tax courses.

The headquarters for a major home improvement chain (Lowe's) is near the university. Each semester, the corporation provides copies of its annual report for all students in tax courses taught by the co-author, Howard Godfrey. Before the first class, the instructor studies the financial statements, the income tax footnote, and other footnotes containing relevant information about accounts affected by Topic 740. The annual reports are distributed on the first day of class, and the instructor leads the class on a journey-moving from the financial statements to the footnotes and back several times as information about various accounts or notes is analyzed.

For example, the footnote for property indicates that the straight-line method of depreciation is used in the financial statements, setting the stage for a visit to the balance sheet and to the tax footnote showing a substantial deferred tax liability for the property. The effective income tax rate found in the tax footnote is verified by referring to the income tax provision in the income statement. The details of the income tax provision in the tax footnote are related to the income tax provision shown in the income statement. The deferred tax asset for net operating losses in foreign jurisdictions and the related valuation allowance account are explained by the instructor, as well as the note indicating that the company has not provided for deferred income taxes for undistributed earnings of foreign subsidiaries. A substantial part of the first class is devoted to studying the annual report. Students are asked to keep their copies of the report for reference later in the semester, especially when the accounting for income tax topic is covered.

Benefits From the Project

In many cases, students in a master of accountancy tax course are just a few months away from starting careers in public accounting (or corporate accounting, etc.). A new graduate may quickly become involved in a "crash course" learning about an important client (or the individual's corporate employer). The graduate may need to quickly learn about the company's (1) business operations; (2) applicable GAAP; (3) tax issues; (4) tax returns; and (5) financial reporting practices.

Students reported the following benefits or discoveries from the project:

• Learning about, and reconciling, book-tax differences using the annual report, tax law, and FASB resources is quite different from learning in a classroom setting or solely from a textbook.

• At the beginning, the project can be somewhat intimidating if they do not have experience studying financial statements.

• Conducting research using a tax research service and the FASB ASC may help when they work simulations on the Uniform CPA Examination.

• The project provides a glimpse into the type of tax issues students will face when preparing tax returns.

It provides an opportunity to learn the language used in financial statements and gain practice thinking analytically.

Getting CPAs Involved in the Project

There is a potential for getting CPAs involved in the project in at least two ways. First, the instructor may have a guest speaker who has a role in preparing the financial statements and the footnotes, either as an accountant or as a tax specialist for the company under study. The speaker may explain the process by which the company accumulates the information for the financial statements and the footnotes, and the process for preparing those documents. The speaker may shed some light on how decisions are made about the need for an allowance account for deferred tax assets, the identification and measurement of uncertain positions, etc. The speaker may be able to use some of the footnotes as a foundation for the presentation and may be able to present some "problems" for classroom discussion. The corporation may understandably limit the scope of the speaker's presentation somewhat, but such a presentation can potentially provide valuable insights for the students and the instructor.

The second alternative is to invite an individual in an accounting firm who has a role related to accounting for income tax, whether as an auditor or as a tax specialist. If the company under study is a client of the firm, discussion of material in the company's annual report would likely be off-limits. However, if the individual is not involved with the company in that way, he or she can provide valuable information about the firm's policies and practices related to determining what should be disclosed, and how it is disclosed in the relevant footnotes of its clients. Other topics may include firm procedures related to deferred tax asset valuation issues and determining the level of authority needed to support tax return positions.

Accounting for income taxes is an exciting and important subject for both students and tax faculty. Many forces collide at the intersection of (1) a government enforcing a complex income tax law; (2) a company seeking to minimize its global income tax burden while providing reliable financial statements to its users; and (3) a CPA firm providing assurance regarding the adequacy of the income tax expense accounts, and other related accounts, and the overall reliability of the financial statements including the footnote disclosures. A project, as described in this column, using a corporation whose headquarters is close to the center of academic study, can provide a helpful bridge for accounting and tax students to see the important intersection of GAAP and tax, and be better prepared for their intended career path.


Contributors

is a professor in the Department of Accounting and Finance at San José State University in San José, Calif. She is a member of the AICPA Tax Division Tax Executive Committee and the Tax Reform Task Force. is a professor of accounting at the University of North Carolina at Charlotte. and are graduates of the Master of Accountancy Program at UNC—Charlotte. Ms. Duong is an international tax associate, and Ms. Humphries is a tax associate, both for Grant Thornton LLP.  For more information about this column, please contact Prof. Godfrey at .

The clean fuel production credit: A new incentive regime

Rights for the r&d credit and sec. 174, irs steps up enforcement of the individual expatriation tax, taxpayer-initiated transfer pricing adjustments in map, trends in enforcement of vat remote-seller rules.

tax assignment conclusion

This article discusses the history of the deduction of business meal expenses and the new rules under the TCJA and the regulations and provides a framework for documenting and substantiating the deduction.

PRACTICE MANAGEMENT

tax assignment conclusion

CPAs assess how their return preparation products performed.

tax assignment conclusion

Get science-backed answers as you write with Paperpal's Research feature

How to Write a Conclusion for Research Papers (with Examples)

How to Write a Conclusion for Research Papers (with Examples)

The conclusion of a research paper is a crucial section that plays a significant role in the overall impact and effectiveness of your research paper. However, this is also the section that typically receives less attention compared to the introduction and the body of the paper. The conclusion serves to provide a concise summary of the key findings, their significance, their implications, and a sense of closure to the study. Discussing how can the findings be applied in real-world scenarios or inform policy, practice, or decision-making is especially valuable to practitioners and policymakers. The research paper conclusion also provides researchers with clear insights and valuable information for their own work, which they can then build on and contribute to the advancement of knowledge in the field.

The research paper conclusion should explain the significance of your findings within the broader context of your field. It restates how your results contribute to the existing body of knowledge and whether they confirm or challenge existing theories or hypotheses. Also, by identifying unanswered questions or areas requiring further investigation, your awareness of the broader research landscape can be demonstrated.

Remember to tailor the research paper conclusion to the specific needs and interests of your intended audience, which may include researchers, practitioners, policymakers, or a combination of these.

Table of Contents

What is a conclusion in a research paper, summarizing conclusion, editorial conclusion, externalizing conclusion, importance of a good research paper conclusion, how to write a conclusion for your research paper, research paper conclusion examples.

  • How to write a research paper conclusion with Paperpal? 

Frequently Asked Questions

A conclusion in a research paper is the final section where you summarize and wrap up your research, presenting the key findings and insights derived from your study. The research paper conclusion is not the place to introduce new information or data that was not discussed in the main body of the paper. When working on how to conclude a research paper, remember to stick to summarizing and interpreting existing content. The research paper conclusion serves the following purposes: 1

  • Warn readers of the possible consequences of not attending to the problem.
  • Recommend specific course(s) of action.
  • Restate key ideas to drive home the ultimate point of your research paper.
  • Provide a “take-home” message that you want the readers to remember about your study.

tax assignment conclusion

Types of conclusions for research papers

In research papers, the conclusion provides closure to the reader. The type of research paper conclusion you choose depends on the nature of your study, your goals, and your target audience. I provide you with three common types of conclusions:

A summarizing conclusion is the most common type of conclusion in research papers. It involves summarizing the main points, reiterating the research question, and restating the significance of the findings. This common type of research paper conclusion is used across different disciplines.

An editorial conclusion is less common but can be used in research papers that are focused on proposing or advocating for a particular viewpoint or policy. It involves presenting a strong editorial or opinion based on the research findings and offering recommendations or calls to action.

An externalizing conclusion is a type of conclusion that extends the research beyond the scope of the paper by suggesting potential future research directions or discussing the broader implications of the findings. This type of conclusion is often used in more theoretical or exploratory research papers.

Align your conclusion’s tone with the rest of your research paper. Start Writing with Paperpal Now!  

The conclusion in a research paper serves several important purposes:

  • Offers Implications and Recommendations : Your research paper conclusion is an excellent place to discuss the broader implications of your research and suggest potential areas for further study. It’s also an opportunity to offer practical recommendations based on your findings.
  • Provides Closure : A good research paper conclusion provides a sense of closure to your paper. It should leave the reader with a feeling that they have reached the end of a well-structured and thought-provoking research project.
  • Leaves a Lasting Impression : Writing a well-crafted research paper conclusion leaves a lasting impression on your readers. It’s your final opportunity to leave them with a new idea, a call to action, or a memorable quote.

tax assignment conclusion

Writing a strong conclusion for your research paper is essential to leave a lasting impression on your readers. Here’s a step-by-step process to help you create and know what to put in the conclusion of a research paper: 2

  • Research Statement : Begin your research paper conclusion by restating your research statement. This reminds the reader of the main point you’ve been trying to prove throughout your paper. Keep it concise and clear.
  • Key Points : Summarize the main arguments and key points you’ve made in your paper. Avoid introducing new information in the research paper conclusion. Instead, provide a concise overview of what you’ve discussed in the body of your paper.
  • Address the Research Questions : If your research paper is based on specific research questions or hypotheses, briefly address whether you’ve answered them or achieved your research goals. Discuss the significance of your findings in this context.
  • Significance : Highlight the importance of your research and its relevance in the broader context. Explain why your findings matter and how they contribute to the existing knowledge in your field.
  • Implications : Explore the practical or theoretical implications of your research. How might your findings impact future research, policy, or real-world applications? Consider the “so what?” question.
  • Future Research : Offer suggestions for future research in your area. What questions or aspects remain unanswered or warrant further investigation? This shows that your work opens the door for future exploration.
  • Closing Thought : Conclude your research paper conclusion with a thought-provoking or memorable statement. This can leave a lasting impression on your readers and wrap up your paper effectively. Avoid introducing new information or arguments here.
  • Proofread and Revise : Carefully proofread your conclusion for grammar, spelling, and clarity. Ensure that your ideas flow smoothly and that your conclusion is coherent and well-structured.

Write your research paper conclusion 2x faster with Paperpal. Try it now!

Remember that a well-crafted research paper conclusion is a reflection of the strength of your research and your ability to communicate its significance effectively. It should leave a lasting impression on your readers and tie together all the threads of your paper. Now you know how to start the conclusion of a research paper and what elements to include to make it impactful, let’s look at a research paper conclusion sample.

Summarizing ConclusionImpact of social media on adolescents’ mental healthIn conclusion, our study has shown that increased usage of social media is significantly associated with higher levels of anxiety and depression among adolescents. These findings highlight the importance of understanding the complex relationship between social media and mental health to develop effective interventions and support systems for this vulnerable population.
Editorial ConclusionEnvironmental impact of plastic wasteIn light of our research findings, it is clear that we are facing a plastic pollution crisis. To mitigate this issue, we strongly recommend a comprehensive ban on single-use plastics, increased recycling initiatives, and public awareness campaigns to change consumer behavior. The responsibility falls on governments, businesses, and individuals to take immediate actions to protect our planet and future generations.  
Externalizing ConclusionExploring applications of AI in healthcareWhile our study has provided insights into the current applications of AI in healthcare, the field is rapidly evolving. Future research should delve deeper into the ethical, legal, and social implications of AI in healthcare, as well as the long-term outcomes of AI-driven diagnostics and treatments. Furthermore, interdisciplinary collaboration between computer scientists, medical professionals, and policymakers is essential to harness the full potential of AI while addressing its challenges.

tax assignment conclusion

How to write a research paper conclusion with Paperpal?

A research paper conclusion is not just a summary of your study, but a synthesis of the key findings that ties the research together and places it in a broader context. A research paper conclusion should be concise, typically around one paragraph in length. However, some complex topics may require a longer conclusion to ensure the reader is left with a clear understanding of the study’s significance. Paperpal, an AI writing assistant trusted by over 800,000 academics globally, can help you write a well-structured conclusion for your research paper. 

  • Sign Up or Log In: Create a new Paperpal account or login with your details.  
  • Navigate to Features : Once logged in, head over to the features’ side navigation pane. Click on Templates and you’ll find a suite of generative AI features to help you write better, faster.  
  • Generate an outline: Under Templates, select ‘Outlines’. Choose ‘Research article’ as your document type.  
  • Select your section: Since you’re focusing on the conclusion, select this section when prompted.  
  • Choose your field of study: Identifying your field of study allows Paperpal to provide more targeted suggestions, ensuring the relevance of your conclusion to your specific area of research. 
  • Provide a brief description of your study: Enter details about your research topic and findings. This information helps Paperpal generate a tailored outline that aligns with your paper’s content. 
  • Generate the conclusion outline: After entering all necessary details, click on ‘generate’. Paperpal will then create a structured outline for your conclusion, to help you start writing and build upon the outline.  
  • Write your conclusion: Use the generated outline to build your conclusion. The outline serves as a guide, ensuring you cover all critical aspects of a strong conclusion, from summarizing key findings to highlighting the research’s implications. 
  • Refine and enhance: Paperpal’s ‘Make Academic’ feature can be particularly useful in the final stages. Select any paragraph of your conclusion and use this feature to elevate the academic tone, ensuring your writing is aligned to the academic journal standards. 

By following these steps, Paperpal not only simplifies the process of writing a research paper conclusion but also ensures it is impactful, concise, and aligned with academic standards. Sign up with Paperpal today and write your research paper conclusion 2x faster .  

The research paper conclusion is a crucial part of your paper as it provides the final opportunity to leave a strong impression on your readers. In the research paper conclusion, summarize the main points of your research paper by restating your research statement, highlighting the most important findings, addressing the research questions or objectives, explaining the broader context of the study, discussing the significance of your findings, providing recommendations if applicable, and emphasizing the takeaway message. The main purpose of the conclusion is to remind the reader of the main point or argument of your paper and to provide a clear and concise summary of the key findings and their implications. All these elements should feature on your list of what to put in the conclusion of a research paper to create a strong final statement for your work.

A strong conclusion is a critical component of a research paper, as it provides an opportunity to wrap up your arguments, reiterate your main points, and leave a lasting impression on your readers. Here are the key elements of a strong research paper conclusion: 1. Conciseness : A research paper conclusion should be concise and to the point. It should not introduce new information or ideas that were not discussed in the body of the paper. 2. Summarization : The research paper conclusion should be comprehensive enough to give the reader a clear understanding of the research’s main contributions. 3 . Relevance : Ensure that the information included in the research paper conclusion is directly relevant to the research paper’s main topic and objectives; avoid unnecessary details. 4 . Connection to the Introduction : A well-structured research paper conclusion often revisits the key points made in the introduction and shows how the research has addressed the initial questions or objectives. 5. Emphasis : Highlight the significance and implications of your research. Why is your study important? What are the broader implications or applications of your findings? 6 . Call to Action : Include a call to action or a recommendation for future research or action based on your findings.

The length of a research paper conclusion can vary depending on several factors, including the overall length of the paper, the complexity of the research, and the specific journal requirements. While there is no strict rule for the length of a conclusion, but it’s generally advisable to keep it relatively short. A typical research paper conclusion might be around 5-10% of the paper’s total length. For example, if your paper is 10 pages long, the conclusion might be roughly half a page to one page in length.

In general, you do not need to include citations in the research paper conclusion. Citations are typically reserved for the body of the paper to support your arguments and provide evidence for your claims. However, there may be some exceptions to this rule: 1. If you are drawing a direct quote or paraphrasing a specific source in your research paper conclusion, you should include a citation to give proper credit to the original author. 2. If your conclusion refers to or discusses specific research, data, or sources that are crucial to the overall argument, citations can be included to reinforce your conclusion’s validity.

The conclusion of a research paper serves several important purposes: 1. Summarize the Key Points 2. Reinforce the Main Argument 3. Provide Closure 4. Offer Insights or Implications 5. Engage the Reader. 6. Reflect on Limitations

Remember that the primary purpose of the research paper conclusion is to leave a lasting impression on the reader, reinforcing the key points and providing closure to your research. It’s often the last part of the paper that the reader will see, so it should be strong and well-crafted.

  • Makar, G., Foltz, C., Lendner, M., & Vaccaro, A. R. (2018). How to write effective discussion and conclusion sections. Clinical spine surgery, 31(8), 345-346.
  • Bunton, D. (2005). The structure of PhD conclusion chapters.  Journal of English for academic purposes ,  4 (3), 207-224.

Paperpal is a comprehensive AI writing toolkit that helps students and researchers achieve 2x the writing in half the time. It leverages 21+ years of STM experience and insights from millions of research articles to provide in-depth academic writing, language editing, and submission readiness support to help you write better, faster.  

Get accurate academic translations, rewriting support, grammar checks, vocabulary suggestions, and generative AI assistance that delivers human precision at machine speed. Try for free or upgrade to Paperpal Prime starting at US$19 a month to access premium features, including consistency, plagiarism, and 30+ submission readiness checks to help you succeed.  

Experience the future of academic writing – Sign up to Paperpal and start writing for free!  

Related Reads:

  • 5 Reasons for Rejection After Peer Review
  • Ethical Research Practices For Research with Human Subjects

7 Ways to Improve Your Academic Writing Process

  • Paraphrasing in Academic Writing: Answering Top Author Queries

Preflight For Editorial Desk: The Perfect Hybrid (AI + Human) Assistance Against Compromised Manuscripts

You may also like, how to write an academic paragraph (step-by-step guide), research funding basics: what should a grant proposal..., how to write an abstract in research papers..., how to write dissertation acknowledgements, how to write the first draft of a..., mla works cited page: format, template & examples, how to write a high-quality conference paper, academic editing: how to self-edit academic text with..., measuring academic success: definition & strategies for excellence, phd qualifying exam: tips for success .

Expenditure and Revenue Assignment: Principles

  • First Online: 06 September 2019

Cite this chapter

tax assignment conclusion

  • Harry Kitchen 4 ,
  • Melville McMillan 5 &
  • Anwar Shah 6  

595 Accesses

1 Citations

This chapter provides a conceptual overview of the principles of expenditure and revenue assignment to local governments. Local government is seen to be more aware of local preferences and conditions and more accountable to local residents than senior governments. Core and noncore responsibilities are distinguished (e.g., local streets versus schooling). Financing follows function. Financing follows the benefit criterion; that is, local residents pay for the local services from which they benefit—with user charges and local taxes although grants may be needed. Various (especially) noncore services involve interjurisdictional spillovers and/or redistributive considerations and so, if assigned to local governments require intergovernmental transfers to achieve efficiency and equity objectives. Financing alternatives and appropriate uses are reviewed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save.

  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
  • Durable hardcover edition

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

The vast number of references found in Bahl and Bird ( 2018 ) and Boadway and Shah ( 2009 ), two books providing comprehensive examinations of fiscal federalism and decentralization, illustrate the growth and extent of the literature. Earlier valuable contributions include those by Bahl and Linn ( 1992 ), Bird et al. ( 1995 ), Litvack et al. ( 1998 ), Manor ( 1999 ), McLure ( 1983 , 1999 ), OECD ( 1987 , 1997 , 1999 ), Owens and Norregaard ( 1991 ), Shah ( 1991 , 1994 ), and Ter-Minassian ( 1997 ).

A resulting additional argument for decentralization is that it enhances political participation. Greater responsiveness, accountability, and enhanced participation have long been seen as advantages of decentralization in the political literature. Other widely noted potential positive features of local government are greater transparency of government to local residents and, of course, greater autonomy. Shah ( 2014 ) advocates for movements toward FAIR (fair, accountable, incorruptible, and responsive) local governance and outlines a framework for evaluation. Blending these desirable characteristics with the economics of fiscal federalism has created a powerful case for decentralization and a more valuable tool for the analysis of decentralized government.

Besley and Coate ( 2003 ) have extended the theory underlying the conventional arguments for decentralization. Their more general model assumes cost sharing of centrally provided outputs under a nationally uniform tax system, allows for non-uniform central provision across localities, locally elected representation to the central government, cooperative and non-cooperative legislative decision-making, varying degrees of heterogeneity in local tastes, and varying interjurisdictional spillovers. Heterogeneity of tastes and the degree of spillovers are central to the centralization-decentralization choice with less heterogeneity and more spillover favoring centralization. However, the case for decentralization is surprisingly strong and prevails even when tastes are uniform and spillovers significant. Also see Ingram and Hong ( 2008 , 17–108).

Critical assessments of fiscal federalism and, particularly, decentralization have emerged—motivated in part by difficulties experienced within some countries. Oates ( 2005 ) characterized those as an emerging second-generation of fiscal federalism. He categorized the second-generation literature (notably in Oates 2008 ) as having two strands. The first strand applies a broader range of economic modeling (i.e., beyond the more conventional public finance) to the questions of fiscal federalism while the second strand evolved from public choice with a focus on political institutions. Both address problems with decentralization that have or might occur. A dominant concern is the problems that emerge with soft (rather than hard) budget constraints on decentralized governments. Essentially, the second-generation literature focuses on problems that can arise when there are flaws in the decentralization design. Surveys of the impacts of decentralization generate mixed results but do point to the importance of good design and implementation (e.g., see Bahl and Bird 2018 , Chapter 2). Also, there is some evidence that better-quality government enhances personal well-being (Helliwell and Huang 2008 ; Helliwell et al. 2018 ) and, though somewhat mixed and deserving of more detailed analysis, that decentralization can also increase well-being/life satisfaction (e.g., Bjornskov et al. 2008 ; Diaz-Serrano and Rodriguez-Pose 2012 ; Gao et al. 2014 ; Tomaney et al. 2011 ). Closely related is a literature on measuring the decentralization of government (e.g., Ivanyna and Shah 2014 ; Hooghe et al. 2010 , 2016 ; Hooghe and Marks 2016 ). The OECD provides valuable recent overviews of fiscal federalism and decentralization (e.g., OECD 2013 , 2016 , 2018 ).

It is important to recognize that borrowing is not a substitute for adequate funding. Debt must be repaid and debt-servicing costs met from the borrowing government’s revenues. Borrowing only facilitates financing long-term capital investments, particularly when they are large and irregular.

For example, see Wiesner ( 2003 ) for a discussion of the role of market-based decentralization in Latin America and Dollery and Wallis ( 2001 ) for a more general discussion of competition in the delivery of public services. Oates ( 1999 ) includes a discussion of market-preserving federalism.

See Tresch ( 2015 , Chapters 26 and 27) for a discussion of a redistributional role for local government.

For further discussion of the topics addressed in this section, see, for example, Dollery and Wallis ( 2001 , Ch 2), Fisher ( 1996 , Ch 6), and Oates ( 1972 ).

See a public finance text (e.g., Fisher 1996 ) for details of the ideal allocation of the cost of public goods. The basic idea is that each individual is charged a personal marginal cost equal to that person’s marginal benefit and the ideal level of output exists when, in the case of a pure public good, the sum of all individual marginal benefits equals the marginal cost of the output.

The problem of distinguishing between economics of sharing and economies of scale is that it is often difficult to distinguish between units of output when many individuals benefit from the same unit of output. For example, there could be economies of scale in the operation of an air pollution abatement system (e.g., cost per unit of particulate matter removed decline to some point) but the benefits of the improvement in air quality resulting from some additional abatement (change in output) could be enjoyed by many or few people (economies of sharing).

For insight into and a brief review of empirical economies of scale analyses, see Byrnes and Dollery ( 2002 ).

For discussion and empirical insights, see McMillan et al. ( 1981 ) and McMillan ( 1989 ).

For illustrations of the assignment of responsibilities among multi-tiered governments, see Table 4.1 of Chap. 4 and Shah ( 2006 , Chapter 1).

Even when services are purely local, citizens may prefer having an upper-level government to review certain activities (e.g., water quality, sewerage treatment, refuse disposal) to provide an informed and independent assessment of performance and especially of the less observable aspects.

See Dahlby ( 2001 ) for a “consensus view” of tax assignments. The shift of the payroll tax to the upper tier(s) of government has been prompted as well by its widespread utilization by senior governments to finance earmarked social benefit programs such as unemployment insurance and social security/pensions.

This treatment reflects the usual top-down perspective on tax assignment in that the matter is decided at the center. In some cases, however, tax assignment is a bottom-up decision where federating states decide upon what tax powers the new central authority should have. See Dahlby ( 2001 ).

In the interests of maintaining the advantages of an internal common market (i.e., free trade within the country) the only taxes, if any, on cross-border movements of goods and services should be national levies on foreign trade.

Bird ( 1999 ) argues that the international adoption of national value-added taxes and their revenue importance have contributed to this centralization.

A broader discussion of transfers—beyond the gap-closing role—appears in the latter part of this chapter.

Dahlby ( 2001 ) notes several problems with the “consensus” view. Those are (a) the need to link expenditure and tax decisions, (b) a need to consider expenditure assignment and grant systems, (c) neglect of distributional impacts of subnational government policies, (d) overlooking certain problems of joint occupancy of tax fields, (e) ignoring that some economic shocks calling for stabilization are region specific, and (f) putting little emphasis on administration and compliance costs of alternative tax assignment regimes.

It is important to remember that property taxes, and especially those taxing improvements as well as land, also may not match benefits exactly and, like a local personal income tax, involve some redistribution. On the other hand, a local personalincome tax may match better benefits and costs for a local service such as schooling.

Kitchen and Slack ( 1993 ) found that about 40 percent of municipal government (i.e., nonschooling) expenditure benefited nonresidential property.

Also see Bahl and Bird ( 2018 , pp. 208–211).

When prices for the services of local government enterprises are above the levels consistent with user charges (e.g., utility charges exceed full costs), the difference is effectively a special sales tax on those services.

For those reasons, Bird ( 1999 ) has recommended a more uniform local business value-added tax.

Besides the references cited below, the following provide valuable insights into intergovernmental transfers: Bird ( 2000 ), Bird and Smart ( 2002 ), Ebel and Yilmaz ( 2001 ), Martinez-Vazquez and Searle ( 2007 ), Shah ( 1999 , 2004 ), and Shah and Thompson ( 2004 ).

At the local government level, however, fiscal disadvantages may be offset in part through capitalization into property values.

Bird ( 1993 ) offers an additional rationale for conditional matching grants. Conditional matching funding can induce local governments to spend some of their own funds on the grantor’s priorities (e.g., achieving minimum standards or greater uniformity of local services) thus stretching the grantor’s budget. While a legitimate perspective, the basis for the mutual interest is in some shared or spillover benefits. Gramlich ( 1977 ) classifies conditional transfers aimed at such grantor policy objectives as also blending the advantages of centralized finance and decentralized supply as having a political-institutional justification. However, because those grants have an efficiency basis, they are distinguished here from the politically motivated grants below.

Bahl, Roy, and Richard M. Bird. 2018. Fiscal Decentralization and Local Finance in Developing Countries . Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.

Book   Google Scholar  

Bahl, Roy W., and Johannes F. Linn. 1992. Urban Public Finance in Developing Countries . New York: Oxford University Press.

Google Scholar  

Besley, Timothy, and Stephen Coate. 2003. Centralized versus Decentralized Provision of Local Public Goods: A Political Economy Approach. Journal of Public Economics 87 (12): 2611–2637.

Article   Google Scholar  

Bird, Richard M. 1993. Threading the Fiscal Labyrinth: Some Issues in Fiscal Decentralization. National Tax Journal 46 (2): 207–227.

———. 1999. Rethinking Subnational Taxes: A New Look at Tax Assignment . IMF Working Paper 165, International Monetary Fund, December.

———. 2000. Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations: Universal Principles, Local Applications . Working Paper 00-02, International Studies Program, School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University, April.

Bird, Richard M., and Michael Smart. 2002. Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers: Some Lessons for International Experience. World Development 30 (6): 899–912.

Bird, Richard M., and Francois Vaillancourt, eds. 1998. Fiscal Decentralization in Developing Countries . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Bird, Richard M., Robert D. Ebel, and Christine I. Wallich, eds. 1995. Decentralization of the Socialist State: Intergovernmental Finance in Transition Countries . Washington, DC: The World Bank.

Bjornskov, Christian, Axel Drehe, and Justina A.V. Fischer. 2008. On Decentralization and Life Satisfaction. Economics Letters 99 (1): 147–151.

Boadway, Robin, and Frank Flatters. 1982. Efficiency and Equalization Payments in a Federal System of Government: Synthesis and Extension of Recent Results. Canadian Journal of Economics 15 (4): 613–633.

Boadway, Robin, and Anwar Shah. 2009. Fiscal Federalism: Principles and Practice of Multiorder Governance . New York: Cambridge University Press.

Burki, Shahid Javed, Guillermo E. Perry, and William R. Dillinger. 1999. Beyond the Center: Decentralizing the State. In World Bank Latin American and Caribbean Studies . Washington, DC: The World Bank.

Byrnes, Joel, and Brian Dollery. 2002. Do Economies of Scale Exist in Australian Local Government? A Review of the Recent Evidence. Urban Policy and Research 20 (4): 391–414.

Council of Europe. 1985. European Charter of Local Self-Government . http://conventions.coe.int/treaty/en/Treaties/Html/122.htm .

Dahlby, Bev. 2001. Taxing Choices: Issues in the Assignment of Taxes in Federations . ISSJ 167/2001, UNESCO. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.

Dethier, Jean-Jacques, ed. 2000. Governance, Decentralization and Reform in China, India and Russia . Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

Diaz-Serrano, Luis, and Andres Rodriquez-Pose. 2012. Decentralization, Subjective Well-Being, and the Perceptions of Institutions. Kyklos 65 (2): 179–193.

Dollery, Brian E., and Joe L. Wallis. 2001. The Political Economy of Local Government . Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

Ebel, Robert D., and Serdar Yilmaz. 2001. Concept of Fiscal Decentralization and Worldwide Overview . Paper presented at the Symposium of the Quebec Commission on Fiscal Imbalance, Quebec City, Quebec, September 13–14.

Fisher, Ronald C. 1996. State and Local Public Finance . Chicago, IL: Richard D. Irwin.

Gao, Song, Xiangyi Meng, and Li Zhang. 2014. Fiscal Decentralization and Life Satisfaction: Evidence from Urban China. Social Indicators Research 119 (3): 1177–1194.

Gramlich, Edward M. 1977. Intergovernmental Grants: A Review of the Empirical Literature. In The Political Economy of Fiscal Federalism , ed. W.E. Oates, 219–239. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.

Helliwell, John F., and Haifang Huang. 2008. How’s Your Government? International Evidence Linking Good Government and Well-Being. British Journal of Political Science 38 (4): 595–619.

Helliwell, John F., Haifang Huang, Shawn Grover, and Shun Wang. 2018. Empirical Linkages Between Good Governance and National Well-Being. Journal of Comparative Economics 46 (4): 1332–1346.

Hooghe, Liesbet, and Gary Marks. 2016. Community, Scale, and Regional Governance: A Postfunctionalist Theory of Governance . Vol. II. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Hooghe, Liesbet, Gary Marks, and Arjan H. Schakel. 2010. The Rise of Regional Authority . New York: Routledge.

Hooghe, Liesbet, Gary Marks, Arjan H. Schakel, Sandra Chapman Osterkatz, Sara Niedzwiecki, and Sarah Shair-Rosenfield. 2016. Measuring Regional Authority: A Postfunctionalist Theory of Governance . Vol. I. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Ingram, Gregory K., and Yu-Hung Hong. 2008. Fiscal Decentralization and Land Policies . Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Ivanyna, Maksym, and Anwar Shah. 2014. How Close Is Your Government to Its People? Worldwide Indicators on Localization and Decentralization. Economics 8: 1–61. https://doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2014-3 .

King, David. 1984. Fiscal Tiers: The Economics of Multi-level Government . London: George, Allen and Unwin.

Kitchen, Harry M., and Enid Slack. 1993. Business Property Taxation . Discussion Paper 93-24, Government and Competitiveness Series, Queen’s University, Kingston, ON.

Litvack, Jennie, Junaid Ahmad, and Richard Bird. 1998. Rethinking Decentralization in Developing Countries , PREM Sector Studies Series. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Manor, James. 1999. The Political Economy of Democratic Decentralization . Washington, DC: The World Bank.

Martinez-Vazquez, Jorge, and Bob Searle, eds. 2007. Fiscal Equalization: Challenges in the Design of Intergovernmental Transfers . New York: Springer.

McLure, Charles E., ed. 1983. Tax Assignments in Federal Countries . Canberra: Australian National University Press.

———. 1999. The Assignment Problem: Conceptual and Administrative Considerations in Achieving Subnational Fiscal Autonomy . Washington, DC: The World Bank.

McMillan, Melville L. 1976. Criteria for Jurisdictional Design: Issues in Defining the Scope and Structure of River Basin Authorities and Other Public Decision Making Bodies. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 3 (1): 46–68.

———. 1989. On Measuring Congestion of Local Public Goods. Journal of Urban Economics 26 (2): 131–137.

McMillan, Melville L., W.R. Wilson, and L.M. Arthur. 1981. The Publicness of Local Public Goods: Evidence from Ontario Municipalities. Canadian Journal of Economics 14 (4): 596–608.

Musgrave, Richard A. 1959. The Theory of Public Finance . New York: McGraw-Hill.

———. 1983. Who Should Tax, Where and What? In Tax Assignments in Federal Countries , ed. C.E. McLure, 2–19. Canberra: Australian National University Press.

Oates, Wallace E. 1972. Fiscal Federalism . New York: Harcourt, Brace Jovanovich.

———. 1993. Fiscal Decentralization and Economic Development. National Tax Journal 46 (2, June): 237–243.

———. 1999. An Essay on Fiscal Federalism. Journal of Economic Literature 27 (3): 1120–1149.

———. 2005. Towards a Second-Generation Theory of Fiscal Federalism. International Tax and Public Finance 12 (4, August): 349–373.

———. 2008. The Evolution of Fiscal Federalism: Theory and Institutions. National Tax Journal 61 (2, June): 313–334.

OECD (Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development). 1987. Managing and Financing Urban Services Growth . Paris: OECD.

———. 1997. Managing Across Levels of Government . Paris: PUMA.

———. 1999. Taxing Powers of State and Local Government . OECD Tax Policy Studies, No. 1, Paris.

———. 2013. Fiscal Federalism 2014: Making Decentralization Work . Paris: OECD Publishing.

———. 2016. Fiscal Federalism 2016: Making Decentralization Work . Paris: OECD Publishing.

———. 2018. Assigning Responsibilities Across Levels of Government . OECD Working Papers on Fiscal Federalism, September. https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/docserver/f0944eae-en.pdf?expires=1551479356&id=id&accname=guest&checksum=3046DD4B5D67CBCB4DCBCDC89D5ECC8D .

Owens, Jeffrey, and John Norregaard. 1991. The Role of Lower Levels of Government: The Experience of Selected OECD Countries. In Local Government: An International Perspective , ed. Jeffrey Owens and Giorgio Panella, 3–54. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

Rondinelli, Dennis. 1999. What is Decentralization. In Decentralization Briefing Notes , ed. J. Litvack and J. Seddon, 2–5. Washington, DC: World Bank Institute.

Shah, Anwar. 1991. The New Federalism in Brazil . The World Bank Discussion Paper #124, Washington, DC.

———. 1994. The Reform of Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations in Developing and Emerging Market Economies, Policy and Research Series, 23 . Washington, DC: The World Bank.

———. 1999. Intergovernmental Transfers and Grants. In Decentralization Briefing Notes , ed. J. Litvack and J. Seddon, 27–31. Washington, DC: World Bank Institute.

———. 2004. Fiscal Decentralization in Developing and Transition Economies: Progress, Problems and the Promise . World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3282, The World Bank, Washington DC, April.

———. 2006. A Comparative Institutional Framework for Responsive, Responsible and Accountable Local Governance. In Local Governance in Industrialized Countries , ed. Anwar Shah, 1–40. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

Chapter   Google Scholar  

———. 2014. Responsibility with Accountability: A FAIR governance framework for performance accountability of local governments. Zbornik Radova Ekonomskog Fakulteta u Rijeci 32 (2): 343–377.

Shah, Anwar, and Theresa Thompson. 2004. Implementing Decentralized Local Governance: A Treacherous Road with Potholes, Detours and Road Closures . World Bank Policy Research Paper 3353, The World Bank, Washington DC, June.

Stigler, George. 1957. Tenable Range of Functions of Local Government. In Federal Expenditure Policy for Economic Growth and Stability , ed. Joint Economic Committee, Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy, 213–219. Washington, DC.

Ter-Minassian, Teresa, ed. 1997. Fiscal Federalism in Theory and Practice . Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

Tiebout, Charles. 1956. A Pure Theory of Public Expenditures. Journal of Political Economy 64 (5): 416–424.

Tomaney, J., A. Pike, G. Torrisi, V. Tselios, and A. Rodríguez-Pose. 2011. Decentralisation Outcomes: A Review of Evidence and Analysis of International Data . Department for Communities and Local Government. https://blogs.ncl.ac.uk/curds/files/2013/02/DecentralisationReport.pdf .

Tresch, Richard W. 2015. Public Finance: A Normative Theory . 3rd ed. Waltham, MA: Academic Press.

Walsh, Cliff. 1992. Fiscal Federalism: An Overview of Issues and a Discussion of Their Relevance to the European Community . Canberra: Federalism Research Centre Discussion Paper No. 2, The Australian National University.

Wiesner, Eduardo. 2003. Fiscal Federalism in Latin America: From Entitlements to Markets . New York: Inter-American Development Bank.

World Bank. 1994. World Development Report, 1994: Infrastructure for Development . Washington, DC: The World Bank and Oxford University Press.

Download references

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Department of Economics, Trent University, Peterborough, ON, Canada

Harry Kitchen

University of Alberta, Edmonton, AB, Canada

Melville McMillan

Governance Studies, Brookings Institution, Washington, DC, USA

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Harry Kitchen .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Kitchen, H., McMillan, M., Shah, A. (2019). Expenditure and Revenue Assignment: Principles. In: Local Public Finance and Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-21986-4_2

Download citation

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-21986-4_2

Published : 06 September 2019

Publisher Name : Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

Print ISBN : 978-3-030-21985-7

Online ISBN : 978-3-030-21986-4

eBook Packages : Economics and Finance Economics and Finance (R0)

Share this chapter

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Publish with us

Policies and ethics

  • Find a journal
  • Track your research
  • Expert Tips for Effective Taxation Assignment Writing

Create a Plan Before You Start Writing Your Taxation Assignment

Erik Ryan

Understanding Your Assignment and Conducting Research

Before starting your taxation assignment, it is essential to fully comprehend the guidelines provided by your professor or educational institution. The foundation for your entire writing process is laid during this crucial step. Spend some time reading through the assignment instructions or prompt, paying close attention to specifics like the topic, scope, word count, and formatting requirements.

The key topics or questions that you must address in your assignment can be found by analyzing the assignment prompt. It ensures that you maintain attention on the goals set by your instructor and helps you understand the task's overall purpose. Understanding the requirements will help you stay on topic and produce an assignment that meets your professor's standards.

You can start the research phase once you are certain that you understand the assignment's requirements. Obtaining pertinent data is the goal here because it will form the basis of your tax assignment. Accurate and current knowledge of taxation concepts, laws, regulations, and practices must be obtained through research.

Choose credible sources that offer dependable and authoritative information when conducting your research. You should think about using academic journals, books, government publications, reputable websites, and government publications. In order to ensure accuracy, make sure to assess the sources' reliability and cross-reference data from various sources.

Investigate various theories and points of view regarding taxes while conducting your research. This will assist you in gaining a thorough understanding of the subject. To gain knowledge about the actual use of taxation concepts, think about looking at recent legislation, case studies, and academic discussions. Your assignment's arguments and analysis will be stronger if your research is more comprehensive and varied.

Gather and Arrange Ideas:

Spend some time organizing your thoughts and brainstorming before starting to write. You can generate a wide range of ideas and potential counterarguments about your taxation assignment by brainstorming. For help visualizing and connecting your main ideas, try using methods like mind maps, outlines, or bullet points

Start by making a list of all the ideas, defenses, and supporting details that come to mind. The objective is to let your thoughts flow freely, so don't worry about organizing them just yet. Review and group your ideas into main points and supporting arguments once you have a sizable list. This will assist you in developing a clear and cogent structure for your assignment.

Think about how your ideas are organized and flow. Make sure that the order in which your main points are presented makes sense and that paragraphs and sections flow naturally. This will improve your assignment's overall readability and make it simpler for your readers to follow your arguments.

Come Up With a Thesis Statement:

The main argument or idea of your taxation assignment is presented in a succinct and narrowly focused statement known as your thesis statement. It serves as a compass, directing the focus and range of your writing. Your thesis should directly address the key questions or issues mentioned in the assignment requirements and be in line with those requirements.

A thorough understanding of the subject matter and the assignment's objectives is necessary to develop a compelling thesis statement. Think about the main points you want to cover, the stance you want to adopt, and the overall point you want to make. As your assignment's main guiding principle, your thesis statement should be crystal clear, succinct, and debatable.

Your readers will be able to identify the main idea of your essay right away with the help of a strong thesis statement. It makes sure that your assignment is entirely focused and coherent, and it also helps them know what to expect.

Form An Outline:

Making an outline is a crucial step in streamlining your ideas and establishing a clear framework for your tax assignment. You can think of an outline as a road map that will lead you through the writing process and make sure you cover all the necessary topics.

Start by segmenting your assignment into sections or subsections according to the key concepts you want to cover. Each paragraph should have a topic sentence that highlights the main idea you want to get across. List the arguments or supporting materials that will help to support your position beneath each main point.

Make sure that the ideas flow logically from one to the next within each section. To further classify and arrange your thoughts, use subheadings, if necessary. This will aid in maintaining a logical flow and make it simple for your readers to follow your assignment.

Keep in mind that an outline is a versatile tool. It is adaptable and can be improved as you write more, allowing for changes and additions to be made as you go. By ensuring that you don't miss any important details, a well-structured outline not only gives your assignment a solid foundation but also saves you time.

Understand and Apply Tax Concepts

Assignments in taxation frequently call for in-depth interpretation of complicated ideas. Write with the intention of elaborating on the fundamental concepts of taxation, including tax law, tax planning, tax liabilities, and tax compliance. It's important to deconstruct these ideas and give understandable justifications so that your readers can follow along.

To show how these ideas are applied in practical situations, back up your explanations with examples. Include case studies, pertinent court rulings, or historical instances to illustrate the application of taxation concepts. By giving specific examples, you help your readers understand what you're saying and show that you can put what you've learned in the classroom to use in real-world scenarios.

A critical evaluation of the benefits and drawbacks of various taxation strategies or policies is also recommended. Examine how taxes affect individuals, businesses, and the economy as a whole. Think about how tax laws will affect society and the economy, as well as how taxation should be done ethically. The depth and caliber of your assignment will be improved by offering a fair analysis of various viewpoints and potential implications.

Provide Evidence to Support Your Positions:

It is crucial to back up your claims with trustworthy evidence in order to make your arguments stronger and give credibility to your taxation assignment. Statistics, research findings, professional judgments, or allusions to pertinent statutes and regulations are examples of evidence.

To support your claims, consult both primary and secondary sources. Original research studies, government statistics, and court records are examples of primary sources. Secondary sources are credible websites, books, or scholarly articles that analyze or summarize earlier research. Follow the proper citation guidelines prescribed by your institution and make sure to properly credit the information's original source.

Select supporting data that complies with your assignment's goals and directly supports your claims. Use current sources instead of skewed or outdated ones that might damage your work's credibility. By supporting your claims with credible evidence, you show that you have a thorough understanding of the subject at hand.

Consider Your Work Critically:

Take the time to critically assess your work before submitting your tax assignment. To guarantee the overall caliber and coherence of your writing, you must complete this step. You can spot any logical inconsistencies, holes in your reasoning, or areas that need more explanation or elaboration by critically assessing your work.

Start by going over your arguments and evaluating the quality of your supporting documentation. Consider whether your points are logically sound and whether they directly address the important issues or questions mentioned in the assignment's specifications. Look for any potential rebuttals or contrarian viewpoints that need to be accounted for.

Consider how your assignment is organized and flows overall. Take into account the logical flow of ideas from one paragraph and one section to the next. To make it simple for your readers to understand your line of reasoning, make sure your thoughts are arranged in a coherent and sequential manner.

Ask a friend or family member to read your assignment aloud. This can assist in locating any awkward wording, murky sentences, or missed grammatical errors. To ensure that your readers are effectively informed of your arguments, pay close attention to how clear and concise your writing is.

Editing and Proofreading:

Editing and proofreading your work is the last step in composing a well-written tax assignment. Proofreading entails thoroughly checking your assignment for grammatical errors, spelling mistakes, punctuation problems, and inconsistent formatting. Clarity, concision, and coherence should all be checked in your writing.

Make sure your writing complies with the correct formatting standards required by your institution. Make sure to use consistent heading, subheading, font, and citation styles throughout your assignment. If there are any grammatical or formatting errors, fix them to prevent your readers from focusing on the content.

Use grammar and spellchecking software to find any remaining errors. But keep in mind that these tools may miss subtle grammatical or contextual differences and are not error-proof. Therefore, it is imperative that you rely on your own meticulous proofreading and editing abilities or ask for help from a reliable peer or mentor.

You can identify any areas that require improvement by reading your assignment several times. It's also helpful to take breaks in between proofreading sessions to keep your mind open. Your taxation assignment will be polished and prepared for submission if you carefully proofread and edit your work.

Conclusion:

For your taxation assignment to be of the highest caliber, you must first develop a thorough plan. You can improve the clarity, coherence, and general quality of your writing by comprehending the assignment requirements, doing extensive research, organizing your thoughts, and using a logical structure.

Spend some time carefully reading the assignment instructions and finding reliable sources for the pertinent information. A clear thesis statement that will direct your writing process should be developed after a brainstorming session. To structure your ideas and guarantee a logical flow, write an outline.

Focus on understanding and interpreting taxation concepts as you write. Provide credible evidence to support your claims, and critically assess your work for coherence and sound reasoning. In order to correct any mistakes and ensure consistent formatting, proofread and edit your assignment one last time.

You can confidently tackle the task at hand and produce an exceptional piece of work that meets the expectations of your professor or educational institution by taking the time to plan your taxation assignment and by adhering to these steps.

Post a comment...

Expert tips for effective taxation assignment writing submit your assignment, attached files.

File Actions

Logo

  • Previous Chapter
  • Next Chapter

A key issue in the literature on fiscal federalism is the question of how subnational authorities might best be financed. This complex issue has no easy solutions, given the wide variety of systems actually applied in different countries and at different times in specific countries. Although there is no ideal system of financing state or regional and local governments, because every country faces different problems and different perspectives, some basic objectives may provide broad guidelines on how tax assignment can best be carried out. Tax assignment can hardly be looked at in isolation. It is an issue intimately related to the question of expenditure assignments across different levels of government, which was discussed in detail in Chapter 2. Even a carefully designed system of intergovernmental expenditure allocation will not work satisfactorily unless it is supported by an equally well-thought-out financing system, and vice versa.

A key issue in the literature on fiscal federalism is the question of how subnational authorities might best be financed. This complex issue has no easy solutions, given the wide variety of systems actually applied in different countries and at different times in specific countries. Although there is no ideal system of financing state or regional and local governments, because every country faces different problems and different perspectives, some basic objectives may provide broad guidelines on how tax assignment can best be carried out. Tax assignment can hardly be looked at in isolation. It is an issue intimately related to the question of expenditure assignments across different levels of government, which was discussed in detail in Chapter 2 . Even a carefully designed system of intergovernmental expenditure allocation will not work satisfactorily unless it is supported by an equally well-thought-out financing system, and vice versa.

This chapter focuses on the questions to be addressed when decisions are being made on tax assignment among different levels of government. The term “tax assignment” here describes the level of government responsible for determining the level and rate structure of various taxes, whether their revenue is to be collected or received by that level, or shared with others.

  • Tax Assignment and Tax Sharing

The general principles of decentralization must guide the assignment of taxes to different levels of government. According to these principles, as laid out in the traditional local finance literature, regional and local governments should ideally fulfill mainly allocational functions by providing services that accrue primarily to the local population, services whose costs the local constituency bears as far as possible. In the same vein, because of the degree of openness of local economies, the literature on fiscal federalism argues in favor of limiting regional and local government roles in economic stabilization, as well as in distributional policies.

In very broad terms, the assignment of funds to local jurisdictions may in principle follow one of three options. The first, and probably least attractive, option assigns all tax bases to local jurisdictions and then requires them to transfer upward part of the revenue to allow the national government to meet its spending responsibilities. As this option may hinder effective income redistribution across the national territory, as well as the effectiveness of fiscal stabilization, it may not represent the most efficient way of raising public resources and may provide inadequate incentives for the local jurisdictions to participate in the financing of the national economy. This system resembles that previously in force in the former Yugoslavia and is somewhat similar to the system of negotiated tax-sharing previously practiced in Russia. The system previously in force in China, generally recognized to have inhibited the government’s ability to pursue stabilization policies, had analogous features to this extreme model.

A second option, on the other extreme, is to assign all taxing powers to the center, and then finance subcentral governments by grants or other transfers, either by sharing total revenue or by sharing specific taxes. The main disadvantage of this option is that it completely breaks the nexus between the level of tax revenue collected and the decisions to spend that revenue, which constitute the basic prerequisite for a multilevel governmental system that enhances efficiency. Without this connection, the risk is that fiscal illusion will lead to overprovision of local government services. Also, because of the risk of frequent, discretionary cuts in transfers to local levels of governments, this system could also make it difficult to establish a stable system of service provision at the local level. This kind of system bears some resemblance to that once applied in the former Soviet Union and in Hungary. Substantial grant financing of local governments is still practiced in a number of industrial countries, such as France, Italy, and the Netherlands.

The third broad option is the more normal one of assigning some taxing power to the local jurisdictions, if necessary (that is, if vertical imbalances persist) complementing the revenue raised locally with tax-sharing arrangements or other transfers from the central government. This option leads directly to the question of which taxes should be assigned to local jurisdictions and which taxes should remain the responsibility of the national government (the tax assignment problem). By assigning taxes and thus letting the local jurisdictions bear the tax burden at the margin associated with expenditure decisions, the budgetary actions of local governments will be guided by tax-benefit considerations and will in this way improve economic efficiency. 1

The tax assignment problem is typically not an either/or problem with a specific tax placed clearly and solely under the responsibility of either the local, the state, or the central government: rather, in reality (for most taxes) a spectrum of different designs exists ranging from full and complete local autonomy to systems with some local discretion and to others with no local autonomy whatsoever. In other words, even if a specific tax, such as an income tax, has been assigned to the local level because it is found to satisfy the criteria for a “good local tax” (see below), it is possible to design the income tax with varying levels of local revenue autonomy. Table 1 illustrates this important point in a very general way by providing a ranking of different tax designs with respect to the degree of autonomy that they leave with the local governments. For the sake of illustration, the table also includes the main nontax sources of revenues for local governments, although obviously a ranking of this nature can only be broadly indicative.

Fiscal Autonomy in Subcentral Governments

Own taxes Base and rate under local control. Overlapping taxes Nationwide tax base, but rates under local control. Nontax revenues Fees and charges. Generally, the central government specifies where such charges can be levied and the provisions that govern their calculation. Shared taxes Nationwide base and rates, but with a fixed proportion of the tax revenue (on a tax-by-tax basis or on the basis of a “pool” of different tax sources) being allocated to the subcentral government in question, based on (1) the revenue accruing within each jurisdiction (also called the derivation principle) or (2) other criteria, typically population, expenditure needs, and/or tax capacity. General purpose grant Subcentral government share is fixed by central government (usually with a redistributive element), but the former is free to determine how the grant should be spent; the amounts received by individual authorities may depend on their tax efforts. Specific grants The absolute amount of the grant may be determined by central government or it may be “open-ended” (that is, depend on the expenditure levels decided by lower levels of government), but in either case central government specifies the expenditure programs for which the funds should be spent.

Complete local fiscal autonomy over revenues requires in principle that local governments can change tax rates and set the tax bases. In many countries, however, the central government either defines local tax bases or sets relatively narrow limits to the capacity of local governments to influence the tax base. In some countries (for example, Norway), the central government also sets out limits to the possible variation of local government tax rates.

Taxes assigned to lower levels of government may take the form of own taxes (sometimes referred to as tax separation systems), defined as taxes accruing solely to lower levels of governments, which can determine the rate and, in some cases, also have some autonomy to influence the tax base. An alternative system is represented by overlapping taxes (sometimes called piggybacking systems of local taxation) with the same (or almost the same) tax base for the different levels of government, but with the right of each level of government to set its own tax rate on that common base. This is the system of personal income taxes applied in, for example, the Nordic countries. In Canada, the income tax system used by the provinces involves levying the tax as a percentage of the federal tax revenue accruing within each province. As opposed to tax separation systems, a system of overlapping taxes may involve administrative advantages with regard to assessing the base and to tax collection. This, however, may be at a potential cost of reduced transparency as the tax levied at each level of government may be less easily identifiable for the taxpayers.

Some, in particular federal, countries prescribe in their constitution the system of tax assignment to be applied. Thus, in India, the Constitution prevents overlapping tax powers so that one type of tax can be levied by only one level of government. Likewise, the modalities of local government taxing powers are specified in the Constitutions of Nigeria and Brazil. In Switzerland, the federal government is prohibited by law from imposing indirect taxes, whereas in Australia a similar rule applies for the states.

The question of local fiscal autonomy may be considered almost completely independent from the question of who actually administers and collects the tax. The allocation of these tasks should be determined on the basis of where they can be carried out most efficiently, although one consideration may be that local accountability may be encouraged if the tax is assessed and collected locally.

Probably the single most critical issue in the discussion of subcentral fiscal autonomy, when looked at from the tax side, is whether the authorities concerned can determine their own tax rates. It could be argued that the case for local discretion, as far as the tax base is concerned, should be limited, because changing tax base definitions (for example, by allowing local governments to set individually the amount of a basic allowance, to introduce special tax reliefs, or to exempt specific sources of income or groups of taxpayers) could lead to distortions in the allocation of resources across localities, and also could have important redistributional consequences—an area in which local autonomy is generally believed to be unwarranted. If local governments cannot alter their tax rates, they cannot alter the level of their services in accordance with local preferences. In some countries, subcentral authorities rely mainly on taxes whose rates are fixed by the central government (for example, the countries with extensive tax-sharing arrangements, such as Portugal and Germany) or whose rate is subject to a ceiling. (Norway is a special case in this regard in that all local governments apply the ceiling rate of the local income tax.)

The importance attached to a lack of discretion in local tax policy depends mainly on the role subcentral authorities are supposed to play. To the extent that they are seen mainly as agents, implementing the policies laid down by other tiers of government, their limited autonomy with respect to tax policy would not appear to be serious. In contrast, if they are meant to implement their own expenditure programs and independently set their service levels in accordance with local preferences, their inability to determine tax rates and thus the level of their own revenues is a serious problem owing to the potential conflict between expectations, needs, and wishes of the local population, and the actual revenue potential available to local governments.

The main arguments against providing subcentral authorities with extensive fiscal autonomy center on the risk of increasing economic disparities between areas or localities and alleged restraints on central government macroeconomic control. Administrative simplicity or administrative economies of scale are also used as arguments for centralized taxes with a specific proportion of tax revenues being allocated to subordinate levels of government.

In what follows, the more specific aspects of tax assignment are dealt with by addressing the basic question of which taxes can be considered good candidates for state and local tax sources and which cannot. What characterizes a good local tax?

A Good Local Tax

A good local tax adequately supports a decentralized public expenditure system. The literature on fiscal federalism and local government finance 2 generally suggests that the following criteria and considerations should form the basis for decisions on which taxes can adequately be assigned to the subcentral level and which should remain at the national level.

To the extent that the tax in question is aimed at, and is suitable for, economic stabilization or income redistribution objectives, it should be left to the responsibility of the central government.

The base for taxes assigned to the local level should not be very mobile, otherwise taxpayers will relocate from high to low tax areas, and the freedom of local authorities to vary rates will be constrained. For this reason, general consumption taxes are found at subordinate levels of government only where geographical areas are very large (for example, Canada and the United States). Thus, the more mobile a tax base, the greater the presumption to keep it at the national level.

Tax bases that are very unevenly distributed among jurisdictions should be left to the central government.

Local taxes should be visible, in the sense that it should be clear to local taxpayers what the tax liability is, thereby encouraging local government accountability.

It should not be possible to “export” the tax to nonresidents, thereby weakening the link between payment of the tax and services received.

Local taxes should be able to raise sufficient revenue to avoid large vertical fiscal imbalances. The yield should ideally be buoyant over time and should not be subject to large fluctuations.

Taxes assigned to the local level should be fairly easy to administer or, in other words, the more important economies of scale in tax administration are for a given tax, the stronger the argument for leaving the tax base for that tax to the national level. Economies of scale may depend on data requirements, such as a national taxpayer identification number and computerization.

Taxes and user charges based on the benefit principle can be adequately used at all levels of governments, but are particularly suitable for assignment to the local level, inasmuch as the benefits are “internalized” to the local taxpayers.

This set of broad criteria translates into more specific recommendations regarding which taxes should be assigned to different levels of government, that is, which taxes may be considered good local taxes and which should be left in the domain of the central government. It is generally acknowledged in the literature 3 that the most obvious candidates as good local taxes are land or property taxes and, to some extent, personal income taxes. With some exceptions, turnover or consumption taxes, as well as taxes on capital income, in particular corporate income taxes, are generally considered less appropriate at the local level and in some cases also at the state level 4 because of the mobility of the corresponding tax bases. This broad conclusion derived from principles of local finance seems in very general terms to conform to the financing system actually found in most countries.

The following discussion addresses these questions on a tax-by-tax basis and is intended to cover all the main taxes to which tax assignment is applied in practice (disregarding whether these taxes according to the general principles are considered appropriate at subordinate levels of government or not). The treatment of the different taxes is also intended to be in descending order of importance for subordinate level of governments, although this ordering must necessarily be somewhat subjective (see Tables 2 and 3 ). 5

Distribution of Tax Revenue Among Different Levels of Government

1 Includes supernational authorities’ share of general government total tax revenue for Belgium (1.5 percent), France (0.7 percent), Germany (0.9 percent), the Netherlands (1.4 percent), and the United Kingdom (1.2 percent).

2 Data for general government do not include local government.

Country and Year Tax as Percentage of GDP Central government State government Local government Central government State government Local government Central government State government Local government Central government State government Local government Central government State government Local government Industrial countries Federal Australia (1991) 30.6 79.7 16.9 3.5 100.0 0.0 0.0 2.4 57.8 39.8 72.5 27.5 0.0 45.2 54.8 0.0 Canada (1989) 34.9 50.9 40.2 8.9 63.5 36.5 0.0 0.0 16.2 83.8 40.1 59.4 0.4 60.0 32.4 7.6 Germany (1991) 41.4 73.4 19.7 6.9 39.1 40.8 20.1 2.0 61.2 36.8 79.1 20.8 0.1 100.0 0.0 0.0 Spain (1990) 34.0 87.0 4.8 8.2 92.9 1.2 6.0 5.8 50.5 45.7 81.1 5.7 13.2 99.2 0.0 0.8 United States (1991) 27.7 65.8 20.5 13.8 81.1 17.1 1.7 6.0 6.7 87.3 16.0 68.3 15.7 97.8 2.2 0.0 Unitary Belgium (1990) 45.6 95.6 n.a. 4.4 90.9 n.a. 9.1 100.0 n.a. 0.0 97.0 n.a. 3.0 99.1 n.a. 0.9 France (1991) 43.1 90.5 n.a. 9.5 100.0 n.a. 0.0 100.0 n.a. 0.0 100.0 n.a. 0.0 81.9 n.a. 18.1 Netherlands (1991) 48.5 97.3 n.a. 2.7 100.0 n.a. 0.0 65.1 n.a. 34.9 100.0 n.a. 0.0 96.3 n.a. 3.7 Norway (1990) 45.2 78.8 n.a. 21.2 47.6 n.a. 52.4 37.9 n.a. 62.1 99.6 n.a. 0.4 97.5 n.a. 2.5 Sweden (1991) 54.2 69.6 n.a. 30.4 24.7 n.a. 75.3 100.0 n.a. 0.0 100.0 n.a. 0.0 100.0 n.a. 0.0 United Kingdom (1991) 35.8 96.0 n.a. 4.0 100.0 n.a. 0.0 99.2 n.a. 0.8 100.0 n.a. 0.0 81.6 n.a. 18.4 Developing countries Federal India (1990) 16.5 65.8 34.2 0.0 100.0 0.0 0.0 33.7 66.3 0.0 49.2 50.8 0.0 88.9 11.1 0.0 Argentina (1989) 14.6 60.4 39.6 0.0 34.2 65.8 0.0 49.2 50.8 0.0 85.8 14.2 0.0 61.0 39.0 0.0 Brazil (1991) 24.5 65.0 30.9 4.1 100.0 0.0 0.0 2.2 40.5 57.3 37.9 57.8 4.3 94.2 5.3 0.5 Mexico (1987) 17.8 85.5 11.6 2.9 98.2 1.3 0.6 1.2 0.0 98.8 99.8 0.1 0.1 5.8 77.0 17.2 Unitary Hungary (1990) 48.6 92.4 n.a. 7.6 71.9 n.a. 28.1 100.0 n.a. 0.0 100.0 n.a. 0.0 100.0 n.a. 0.0 Poland (1988) 44.6 78.7 n.a. 21.3 75.9 n.a. 24.1 48.3 n.a. 51.7 85.8 n.a. 14.2 78.5 n.a. 21.5 Israel (1990) 34.7 93.1 n.a. 6.9 100.0 n.a. 0.0 12.3 n.a. 87.7 100.0 n.a. 0.0 98.3 n.a. 1.7 Thailand (1990) 19.7 95.6 n.a. 4.4 100.0 n.a. 0.0 81.9 n.a. 18.1 92.1 n.a. 7.9 100.0 n.a. 0.0 Chile (1988) 20.5 96.2 n.a. 3.8 100.0 n.a. 0.0 19.7 n.a. 80.3 96.5 n.a. 3.5 100.0 n.a. 0.0 Kenya (1991) 23.3 98.3 n.a. 1.7 100.0 n.a. 0.0 0.0 n.a. 100.0 99.5 n.a. 0.5 100.0 n.a. 0.0 South Africa (1990) 27.4 94.5 1.2 4.3 100.0 n.a. 0.0 25.5 n.a. 74.5 96.7 3.3 0.0 100.0 n.a. 0.0 Zimbabwe (1986) 31.3 96.4 n.a. 3.6 100.0 n.a. 0.0 11.5 n.a. 88.5 98.2 n.a. 1.8 98.7 n.a. 1.3
Tax Revenue in Percentage of Corresponding General Government Tax
Total tax Income tax Property tax Domestic taxes on goods and services Other taxes

Distribution of Different Taxes Within Different Levels of Government

(In percent)

2 There are no state governments in unitary countries.

3 No data on local governments are available.

Country and Year Income tax Property tax Domestic taxes on goods and services Other taxes Income tax Property tax Domestic taxes on goods and services Other taxes Grants as percentage of taxes plus grants Income tax Property tax Domestic taxes on goods and services Other taxes Grants as percentage of taxes plus grants Industrial countries Federal Australia (1991) 71.9 0.3 22.8 5.1 0.0 30.1 40.9 28.9 58.8 0.0 100.0 0.0 0.0 29.9 Canada (1989) 59.3 0.0 21.3 19.4 43.1 3.6 39.9 13.3 21.9 0.0 84.6 1.4 14.0 53.7 Germany (1991) 16.1 0.1 31.5 52.4 62.5 6.6 30.9 0.0 19.2 88.2 11.4 0.4 0.0 44.7 Spain (1990) 33.2 0.4 24.7 41.7 7.6 60.9 31.3 0.2 77.0 22.6 31.1 42.7 3.6 45.1 United States (1991) 55.1 1.1 4.1 39.7 37.4 3.9 55.8 2.9 28.9 5.6 75.3 19.1 0.0 47.6 Unitary Belgium (1990) 35.1 2.7 25.6 36.7 75.8 0.0 17.2 7.0 62.1 France1 (1991) 19.1 2.8 30.6 47.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 44.7 Netherlands (1991) 33.3 2.3 23.7 40.6 0.0 43.9 0.0 56.1 90.2 Norway (1990) 21.5 1.4 44.7 32.3 87.7 8.6 0.7 3.0 45.9 Sweden (1991) 14.4 4.6 35.5 45.5 100.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 21.5 United Kingdom (1991) 39.1 8.5 33.9 18.4 0.0 1.6 0.0 98.4 85.8 Developing countries Federal India (1990) 18.6 0.5 44.9 36.0 0.0 1.8 89.5 8.7 48.7 Argentina (1989) 6.1 5.2 17.1 71.5 17.9 8.2 4.3 69.5 0.0 Brazil (1991) 22.5 0.1 27.9 49.5 0.0 4.3 89.8 5.9 23.3 0.0 45.5 50.6 3.9 77.5 Mexico (1987) 26.5 0.0 72.5 1.0 2.5 0.0 0.4 97.1 3.3 4.4 7.9 2.3 85.4 5.5 Unitary Hungary (1990) 21.2 0.1 37.1 41.6 100.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 59.4 Poland (1988) 32.0 2.2 32.0 33.8 37.5 8.7 19.6 34.2 29.8 Israel (1990) 42.4 1.0 39.1 17.5 0.0 96.0 0.0 4.0 50.0 Thailand (1990) 26.2 3.6 45.0 25.1 0.0 17.0 83.0 0.0 32.9 Chile (1988) 30.7 0.5 48.8 20.0 0.0 56.0 44.0 0.0 52.1 Kenya (1991) 29.3 0.0 53.7 17.0 0.0 84.2 15.3 0.5 0.0 South Africa (1990) 54.6 1.6 36.6 7.2 0.0 0.0 100.0 0.0 91.5 0.0 100.0 0.0 0.0 37.5 Zimbabwe (1986) 47.6 0.4 32.8 19.2 0.0 77.4 15.7 6.9 80.8
Central Government State Government Local Government
  • Property Taxes

Property taxes, including in particular land taxes, have historically been widely used as subcentral taxes without any special regard to their alleged incidence. This is the outcome of the perceived advantages of the property tax as a local tax. With a property tax it is always clear which authority is entitled to the revenue it yields, which is not always so for income taxes and other taxes. Administration costs are generally found to be lower for a property tax (provided that there is a registry of properties with updated values) than for an income tax, which requires complex tax returns. The yield of a property tax can be predicted more accurately than for an income tax or a profits tax. Finally, some of the tax will be levied on businesses, which seems reasonable to the extent that businesses derive benefits from subcentral services, such as roads and other infrastructure services.

An additional argument for the use of property taxes is that, while almost all residents pay directly or indirectly (through rents) the property tax, thus avoiding free-rider problems in local service provision, this is not always the case for local income taxes. It has also been argued that property taxes are guided by the benefit principle of taxation to the extent that the corresponding spending by local governments benefits local properties by increasing their value. Against this view, it could be held that, although land and existing structures and thus the tax base cannot move in a physical sense, the tax base can do so in a fiscal sense via the capitalization of property taxes to the extent that property taxes are not used for purposes viewed as beneficial to property owners.

The main disadvantage of property taxes lies in the fact that they almost universally realize lower amounts than needed. There are many reasons for this, including the fact that it is a very visible tax (and thus politically unpopular), that it is perceived to have unwanted distributional consequences to the extent that the tax is borne by renters and not by owners of property, and that there are problems associated with the measurement of the tax base, including in particular the “correct” valuation of property, and its updating.

Some countries prefer to distinguish between residential property and commercial and industrial property, with the former being assigned to local taxation, and the latter either to local taxation with a uniform rate or to national taxation only (as is the case in some Nordic countries). In this regard, a particularly contentious issue in many countries (whether industrial, developing, or in transition) has been the taxation of agricultural land. In countries with a general income tax (including income from agriculture), a tax on land could be seen as a discriminatory surcharge on a basic factor input in one sector of the economy, rather than a local benefit tax. In countries without an income tax on agriculture, it has been argued that a land tax on agriculture impedes the development of this important foreign exchange earning sector. Whatever the merits of these arguments may be, the relatively modest tax burden on agriculture found in most countries (which is generally independent of the level of development of the countries in question) seems to reflect the political influence of this sector rather than economic principles or sound fiscal policies.

Other countries apply alternative criteria for the assignment of property taxes to different levels of government. In Brazil, for example, urban property is taxed at the municipal level, while the federal government levies and administers the tax on rural property.

More specifically, at least four important issues relate to the definition and measurement of the base upon which property taxes are levied: the coverage of the base, the use of capital or rental values, the number and nature of exemptions, and the frequency and methods of updating property values. The main issue regarding coverage has been whether land, improvements to land, and buildings should all be subject to tax. The systems applied vary substantially between countries, although most of the countries for which information is available include the unimproved value of land, the value of land improvements, and usually also the value of buildings. The efficiency and equity implications of property taxes have been intensively debated in the literature and will not be pursued further here (see McLure (1977) for an overview of the issues).

In principle, the impact of using rental values or capital values should be the same, assuming well-functioning property and capital markets. It has been argued, however, that there may be major differences in the actual outcome to the extent that rental values reflect mainly the current use of the property, while capital values are said to reflect the value of the property in the best alternative use. Also in this regard, actual methods vary between countries. Capital values are generally based upon market values, although some countries apply corrections to these market values (for example, use a specific proportion of the market value).

Most countries apply a large number of different reliefs under the property tax, for example, in the form of exemption of government property, highways, railways, and other transport or communication facilities, and mining, agriculture, and forestry industries. The subsidies implicit in this kind of treatment, not least with respect to agricultural land, have been increasingly criticized in a number of countries. As indicated above, many countries apply different tax treatment to residential and business property, with residential property usually subject to a more favorable treatment.

A particularly contentious problem in a number of countries has been the frequency and method used to update property values. Thus, in most developing countries, assessment of property values and updating seem to be the major issues. The unpopularity of this type of tax may in some countries be associated with infrequent updates of values, leading to large and abrupt increases in tax liabilities when updating actually takes place. Although property valuations are generally based on market prices, problems are also encountered during certain periods and in areas with modest turnover of property. State and central governments usually perform the valuation of property in order to achieve the necessary coordination between different areas, but the way in which and frequency with which it is done vary substantially across countries.

Although most of the revenue from property taxes generally accrues to subcentral levels of government, state or local governments do not always have complete discretion over the base or the rate. Central governments typically set the rules governing valuations and their frequency and determine exemptions and other reliefs. Also, the central government may impose restrictions on the variations in property tax rates. In practice, local government discretion may be limited in other ways, for example, in the form of earmarking of property revenues, or if higher rates adversely affect grants (as in the United Kingdom before 1989). In Italy, the central government sets a minimum rate for the property tax. If a municipality does not apply the floor rate, transfers to it from the central government are supposed to be reduced correspondingly. Thus, although most of the revenue from property taxes primarily accrues to subcentral authorities in most countries, the respective central governments are generally heavily involved in formulating and administering the provisions of the taxes.

  • Personal Income Taxes

Most countries assign all or a large proportion of personal income taxes to the central government. Exceptions include the Scandinavian countries, Switzerland, the Baltic countries, Russia, and the other countries of the former Soviet Union. Generally, there are advantages as well as disadvantages of using personal income taxes at the subcentral level. Among the advantages is the fact that personal income taxes generally are buoyant and thus capable of raising the necessary revenue, and in addition they are believed not to fall on businesses, thereby avoiding the risk of subcentral authorities, anxious to attract new industry, indulging in tax-cutting competitions with adverse effects on services provided.

One of the main disadvantages of a local income tax as the main revenue raiser is the fact that, depending on the level of the tax threshold, many people may not pay the tax, although they receive local services. 6 This could have an adverse impact on the way a decentralized system works and has been used as an argument for supplementing an income tax with other tax sources, thereby including the majority of the local constituency in the local tax net. In this regard, two schools of thought may be distinguished. First, many countries (including, for example, most Mediterranean countries and Austria) seem to place considerable weight on income redistribution and on making income tax systems easy to administer by setting a high tax threshold, thereby excluding a large proportion of the population from the tax net. In contrast, other countries (such as New Zealand, Switzerland, and the Scandinavian countries) generally put more emphasis on the inclusion of most of the population in the tax net by setting relatively low tax thresholds, so that more people share the cost of public services.

In the context of financing local governments, there seems to be a case for making a distinction between schedular and global income taxes, since schedular income taxes can in some cases be used by local jurisdictions without great difficulties, in particular if the taxes on, for example, interest income, dividend income, and wages and salaries are withheld at source and constitute the final tax paid. However, the more developed is a country, the higher is the likelihood that individuals receive income from different sources, and furthermore that these incomes are derived from different jurisdictions. This may move countries to prefer a global income tax system in which the different income sources are added together for each individual and the tax liability is adjusted according to individual circumstances. 7 For such a system to work well at the local level, it requires flows of information on personal income received from other jurisdictions and thus poses the risk of tax evasion. Against this background, it may be better to leave a global income tax base with the national government, which is in a better position to acquire the necessary information.

However, such a system can be combined with revenue sharing, such as is the case in India, where the states receive about 85 percent of total income tax revenue, allocated on the basis of population, tax effort, and a measure of backwardness. In Brazil, 44 percent of the income tax revenue is transferred to lower level governments under a tax-sharing arrangement, and in Poland, in 1992, 15 percent of the personal income tax revenue was shared with local governments. As part of a recent reform of intergovernmental fiscal relations, shared personal income taxes have also been introduced in Hungary (in 1991, 50 percent of the revenue accrued to local governments). Similar tax-sharing arrangements were also important elements in the financing reform in China in 1980 (under the present financing arrangements, local governments receive all of the yields from personal income taxes).

Notwithstanding these considerations, and to the extent that the administrative capabilities are present at the national level, there is a fairly easy and cost-effective way of taxing a global income tax base in local jurisdictions, namely for the local jurisdictions to use the same statutory tax base as for the national income tax (that is, overlapping taxes or piggybacking). This solution, which reduces administrative as well as compliance cost, is actually used in a number of countries (such as, for example, the Nordic countries and Canada, where the provincial tax is levied as a percentage of the federal tax). 8 However, although it introduces an additional complexity to the tax and thus offsets at least in part some of the administrative savings, some of the countries applying this system (for example, the United States) also use specific tax reliefs in their state and local tax systems. Thus, the extent to which countries using overlapping income taxes coordinate the taxes levied at different levels varies considerably. In the Scandinavian countries and Canada, for example, there is a high degree of coordination, while coordination is lacking in Switzerland and the United States.

Generally, because the system requires a fairly advanced administrative system with up-to-date recording of taxpayers’ residence, overlapping personal income taxes are generally seen only in developed countries. Combined with an efficient equalization system, such a system is seen, in the countries that apply it, to ensure that variations in tax rates across jurisdictions reflect similar differences in locally determined service levels. Even in industrial countries, however, the administrative recording requirements have been used as an argument against the workability of local income taxes (which, for example, is the case in the United Kingdom).

A special case of overlapping personal income taxes (or partly overlapping income taxes, if some differences in tax bases are allowed) arises when local income taxes, as in the United States, are deductible from federal income tax liability (deductibility is not applied in the majority of countries using overlapping personal income tax systems). The rationale of such a system is the protection it provides for the taxpayer against excessive aggregate marginal tax rates as a result of high local income taxes. An unwarranted side effect may, however, be the incentive for local governments to expand their expenditures, partly financed—at the margin—by nonresidents. It may also reduce the overall level of progressivity of the tax system.

Taxes on income deriving from the activities of small business establishments or from agriculture may often be imposed as efficiently by local governments as national governments, and in some cases local governments may even possess more information than national governments. However, since record keeping by small establishments is often modest or even absent, taxation of such business income has in many cases to rely on presumptive income, based for example on gross sales, on the floor space in which the activity takes place, or on other criteria (for example, in Hungary, the local business tax is levied on the gross turnover of businesses at a maximum rate of 0.3 percent). Taxes on income from small businesses, from self-employed, and from agriculture, with the revenues accruing mostly or solely to local governments, are well known in a number of Central and Eastern European economies in transition, including Poland and Romania, as well as in a number of developing countries, such as India.

Notwithstanding which level of government actually receives the revenue of personal income taxes, practice differs substantially across countries with regard to which level is responsible for the assessment and for the collection of the income taxes at the subordinate level. National or central government responsibility, or—at the most—state responsibility, seems, however, to be the main rule owing principally to the economies of scale involved in the administration of these taxes.

  • Sales Taxes

The popularity of assigning property taxes—and to some degree also income taxes—to subordinate levels of government is attributable in part to the fact that, with these taxes, differences in tax rates between areas are unlikely to cause serious problems owing to the relative immobility of the tax bases. In contrast, different sales tax rates between different jurisdictions can drive consumers (or rather their purchases) away from high tax areas, as is perhaps best reflected in the serious cross-border trade problems between countries with different tax systems and tax levels (such as between Canada and the United States, and between Ireland and the United Kingdom). A distinction must be made, however, between single-stage sales taxes, such as excises and retail taxes, and multistage sales taxes, such as turnover taxes and value-added taxes (VATs).

Retail sales taxes and excises levied on the final sale to the consumer can be given to local jurisdictions as a revenue source, provided that they do not levy these taxes with highly different tax rates. If they do, citizens will be encouraged to shop in other jurisdictions. The main factors determining the extent to which this will take place are the vicinity of other jurisdictions, the cost of travel, and the value of the goods purchased. 9 Another constraining factor for the use of such taxes at the local level with anything but a modest level of tax rates is the risk of tax evasion, which may be relatively more serious for these (single-stage) sales taxes, especially under high tax rates. However, the existence of, for example, both state and municipal sales taxes in many countries must reflect the fact that these caveats are not universally perceived as serious. Thus, in India, the main revenue source of the states is the sales tax. Turnover taxes and some excises are also important provincial revenue sources in Argentina.

A case can be made for distinguishing between excises on goods, which generally should be assigned to the central level to minimize tax exporting, and excises on selected services, consumed locally, and thus much less prone to tax exporting. Some countries, such as India, assign selected excises to the central government (combined with a tax-sharing scheme), and other excises to state and local governments. A number of countries use local excises or special taxes on automobiles or on fuels, which could be regarded as benefit taxes associated with the costs to local governments of maintaining roads. Municipalities in Brazil are allowed to levy a 3 percent tax on retail sales of fuels and gas. In Poland, own sources of revenue for local governments include a tax on automobiles.

Some countries combine earmarking sales taxes with tax assignment to different levels of government. In Russia, for example, a system of regional and federal road funds is in place, financed in part by excises on fuel and on vehicles, supplemented by taxes on registration and ownership of vehicles.

Sales taxes levied at the manufacturing level should, as a general rule, be assigned to the upper tier of government and to subordinate levels of government only where geographical areas are large.

There seems to be broad albeit not universal consensus in the literature that VATs are most appropriately assigned to the central level of government. This dictum rests on the fairly extensive administrative capabilities required to operate the tax (a requirement that is generally best met by central governments) in combination with the need to make the VAT neutral with respect to the spatial allocation of production and consumption, implying that—generally—the VAT should conform to the destination principle. 10 Implementation of this principle requires, however, border control between jurisdictions if the tax is to be levied by individual provinces or states. This would in most countries be neither feasible nor desirable because of the administrative costs implied and because of the impediments to the free flow of goods and services it would create. In addition, a subnational VAT system would pose problems with regard to which provinces or states should receive the revenues from VAT on imports, and which should bear the burden of VAT refunds on exports. 11 Following this kind of reasoning, comprehensive VATs should be left solely with the national government, as is, in fact, the case in most countries. In some countries (for example, China, Germany, and Russia), central VAT revenues may be shared with subnational levels, although this raises the same kind of problems referred to above, if the tax sharing is based on the derivation principle.

Similar considerations on different aspects of VAT design constitute important elements in the ongoing tax reform discussion in India, which contemplates introducing a comprehensive VAT to replace existing excises and sales taxes, with the aim of sharing the revenue between the three levels of government. However, one of the main questions is whether such a system could function properly without fundamental changes in the present system of intergovernmental fiscal relations in India. According to Bird (1993) , it could prove difficult to establish consensus on a formula distributing the VAT proceeds in a context of sharp regional inequalities as the one currently prevailing in that country. Bird also questions the rationale behind sharing the proceeds of any particular tax, because it would seem doubtful that the central government would go through the pain of increasing tax revenues that will accrue in large part to other governments. A more satisfactory alternative—according to Bird—would be to share with the states a fixed share of aggregate central tax revenues.

Brazil offers an example of a VAT assignment system that is generally believed to have had detrimental effects on economic performance. All three levels of government in Brazil are assigned taxing powers on consumption, but with different tax systems, and with the tax covering the widest base, the VAT-type ICMS assigned to state governments and not to the federal government. Furthermore, a large fraction of the federal government consumption tax (the IPI) is transferred to lower levels of governments under a tax-sharing arrangement. This particular design is believed to encourage tax competition between entities of government and to foster tax evasion, which is, furthermore, exacerbated by a large number of different tax rates and exemptions (see Chapter 18 for details).

  • Corporate Profit Taxes

There seems to be almost universal agreement that the taxation of larger businesses, and in particular corporate profit taxes, should be left to the national level and to provinces or states only where these are very large (as in Canada). This reflects the fact that the economic activities of corporations are typically much more diversified and complex, with factor inputs originating from a number of jurisdictions (and possibly also from abroad), and with sales similarly going to a multitude of jurisdictions. Depending on the nature of the specific markets in question, local taxes on corporate profits would to a large degree be exported or shifted to other jurisdictions in a nontransparent way, thus rendering the associated tax burden almost imperceptible to local citizens. In addition, a high local-tax rate may lead the business entity in question to move the tax base to other jurisdictions, either by physically moving the corporation or by adjusting the internal transfer pricing arrangements.

Leaving the taxation of corporate profits entirely in the hands of local governments would thus create serious informational problems because of the administrative issues associated with the allocation of taxable profits between different jurisdictions in cases of enterprises with economic activity spread over many localities. But also in this case these problems could, at least in part, be overcome by some form of overlapping tax bases between the national and the local level (piggybacking), although the room for tax-rate variations is much smaller for the corporate profits tax than for personal income taxes. In Canada, the base is harmonized to a considerable degree between the provinces and the federal level (although provinces do have the possibility of providing individual investment incentives), while provinces have the flexibility to vary rates. In Brazil, the states can levy a 5 percent surcharge on the corporate income tax.

Some countries have, with the above-mentioned problems in mind, chosen instead to allocate a fixed portion of the profit tax revenue originating within each jurisdiction to the local governments under a tax-sharing arrangement. Thus, Russia allocates 25 percentage points of the 38 percent tax rate on corporate profits to regional governments, while the remaining 13 percentage points remain with the federation. 12 Of the corporate tax revenue in Poland in 1992, 5 percent was shared with local governments. In Nigeria, a special system is in force according to which the federal authority has the legal jurisdiction over the company tax, but the states nevertheless collect the tax and retain the proceeds.

  • Payroll Taxes

Like VATs and corporate profit taxes, different types of payroll taxes are also generally seen as an appropriate revenue source for the central government only, because different payroll tax rates could drive employers, and jobs, away from high tax areas. In addition, tax exporting is probably significant in the sense that, first, part of the tax may be shifted to prices and thus borne by consumers outside the jurisdiction that receives the revenue, and, second, the tax may be levied on employees with residence outside the revenue-receiving jurisdiction. Thus, the tax may not be visible to the local taxpaying constituency, and the relationship may be weak between tax payments and services provided by jurisdictions. 13

Notwithstanding these general considerations, tax-sharing arrangements for payroll taxes actually exist in a few countries. A relatively small payroll tax is also levied by the states in Australia.

  • Natural Resource Taxes

Taxes on natural resources are generally perceived as poor candidates for local taxation, since normally the base of these taxes is very unevenly distributed across jurisdictions. In addition, extraction of economic rent from natural resources could be held to be a national prerogative, which should benefit the whole of the nation and not just selected fortunate regions. The taxes in question are also in many cases characterized by a high level of revenue volatility owing to price fluctuations. The associated uncertainty, it could be argued, should be absorbed by the central government, which generally has a number of alternative revenue sources at its disposition, and not by regional or local governments, which are meant primarily to conduct allocative functions (price fluctuations on oil, for example, have created sharp swings in the revenues of states in Nigeria). These theoretical considerations, however, do not take into account the important fact that, in practice, cultural and ethnic differences may be the reason for strong pressures toward regional independence, including regional control over natural resources, as is seen, for example, in Russia.

Alternatively, it could be held that, at least in part, these taxes should be considered as benefit taxes, that is, as payments for the benefits deriving from the provision by local or regional governments of the necessary infrastructure investment without which either exploitation of the natural resources would not be possible, or the return to the investments required could be significantly reduced. In other cases, the taxes may be considered as compensation for the environmental costs associated with the exploitation of natural resources. This might also constitute part of the reason why a number of countries actually operate tax-sharing schemes for natural resource taxation (see country chapters for details). In Russia, local governments in regions rich in natural resources benefit from the retention of a high share of these taxes. Previously, in Nigeria, all taxes accruing from oil production went to the states. In Argentina, a revenue-sharing scheme is in place for royalties on mineral extraction.

  • Import and Export Taxes

Import and export taxes, apart from being generally considered inferior to the taxes dealt with above, should always be imposed by the national government to reduce the possibility of introducing major distortions within the country through differential foreign trade taxes imposed by different jurisdictions. In fact, the large majority of countries assign import duties exclusively to the central government (Nigeria being one exception, with import tax revenue being shared). Nevertheless, in some countries, such as Russia, the formula for sharing important export tax receipts with regions from which the exports originate remains an important tax policy issue (because of the nature of the exports in question, these taxes may as well be considered special cases of taxes on natural resources). India operates a special tax on interstate sales with a maximum rate of 4 percent, and with a number of exemptions (see Chapter 21 for details).

  • Benefit Taxes and User Charges

In addition to what has been said above about specific sources of taxation, it is generally held that benefit taxes, license fees, and user charges should all be used to the maximum extent feasible at the local level because they are transparent, they minimize the risk of tax exporting, they generally do not involve problems of vertical or horizontal equity, and they increase economic efficiency. Although these charges are significant sources of revenue for the localities, they are generally modest compared with some of the taxes considered above.

  • Tax Assignment in Practice

A striking feature of the financing of subcentral levels of government is the significant variation in the level and composition of local government taxation across countries. This feature is illustrated in Tables 2 and 3 , which for a fairly limited sample of countries show the attribution of total tax revenues to subsectors of general government as percentage of total tax revenue, in federal as well as in unitary countries, and the composition of the tax revenue for each subcentral level of government with respect to different types of taxes (including revenues from the tax-sharing arrangements). These tables by their nature do not indicate the actual degree of state, provincial, or local autonomy over the tax revenues, which, as discussed this chapter, may vary considerably across countries.

Nevertheless, as the tables show, most countries have more than one subcentral tax (although the tables do not distinguish between cases where revenues are solely assigned to the subcentral level and where they are shared under tax-sharing arrangements), and this holds for industrial as well as for developing countries, and for federal as well as for unitary countries. Generally, the personal income tax seems (as expected) to be of greater importance for the subcentral level in industrial countries than in developing countries, although for example in most Anglophone countries the property tax is the dominant tax, especially at the local level (this holds in Australia, Canada, the United States, Ireland, New Zealand, and, until 1990, the United Kingdom).

In some, especially federal, countries, general consumption taxes and in some cases also excises play a considerable role, particularly at the state level (for example, in Austria, Brazil Canada, Germany, India, South Africa, Spain, and the United States). A predominant feature seems to be that these taxes are used by large countries with correspondingly large subcentral areas. Also, in some of these countries, consumption tax systems take the form of tax-sharing arrangements with little or no state or local discretion, as in the case of the Austrian and German VAT.

A common feature not shown in these tables is the dominant use of personal income taxes at the subcentral level as opposed to corporate income taxes, reflecting the fact that corporate income taxes are generally considered unsuitable at the subcentral level owing to the mobility of the tax base.

Although the property tax is among the most popular subcentral taxes, not least in federal industrial countries and unitary developing countries, its revenue measured as a percentage of GDP is generally modest and seldom exceeds about 3 percent. This is probably because it is a highly visible tax, it is hard to evade, there are problems associated with the valuation of property, and it is generally perceived as a regressive tax. For these reasons, the property tax has become increasingly unpopular politically, which may also help to explain why its importance as a revenue source has declined in many countries during the last decade or so.

  • Concluding Remarks

The theory on fiscal federalism provides some fairly broad guidelines with regard to which taxes can appropriately be assigned to subnational levels of government and which should be kept at the central level. However, although some general patterns in accordance with these guidelines can be identified in country practices, even fairly homogeneous countries at the same level of development have in many cases chosen different solutions to these problems. One of the main reasons for this is that the historical, geographical, ethnic, and constitutional character of each country has profound implications for the range of feasible and efficient tax assignment policies.

Some lessons may nevertheless be drawn from actual country experiences. First is the importance of tax administration: a decentralized fiscal system cannot function satisfactorily without the necessary administrative capabilities at the subcentral level. In other words, the design of tax systems should clearly be adapted to the level and quality of administrative resources that have been found politically appropriate to devote to the subcentral levels of government. Generally, the more complicated the tax in question is made for other reasons (for example, for reasons of revenue or equity), the stronger the argument for placing the tax with a higher or the highest tier of government. As a reflection of this “rule,” more complex systems of taxation are generally assigned to subcentral levels of governments only in more developed countries.

Second, in addition to the crucial question of the choice of tax sources at subordinate levels of government, actual experience indicates that a decentralized system will work satisfactorily only if state, provincial, and local governments are given at least one major own source of revenue, that is, a source of revenue over which they have autonomy to determine the revenue (assuming that this system is supported by adequate equalization of tax capacities and expenditure needs). Only then can a multilevel system of government promote accountability and ultimately economic efficiency.

Finally, there are obvious potential gains as well as risks associated with decentralizing taxing powers. The gains include improved mobilization of revenue sources and the potential efficiency gains alluded to above. The risks take the form of leaving the central government in a more vulnerable position with respect to its ability to conduct effective fiscal policies, especially for stabilization purposes.

This assumes chat there are no substantial externalities associated with the provision of local services, that the tax cannot be shifted to other jurisdictions, and that an efficient equalization scheme is in place.

For general expositions of the principles of fiscal federalism, see Oates (1972) and King (1984) .

See in particular King (1984) , Musgrave and Musgrave (1980) , and Oates (1972) .

Unless the areas in question are large as is the case in, for example, Canada and the United States.

As illustrated in Tables 2 and 3 , the importance of different tax sources varies considerably across countries. Based on more comprehensive information than that presented here, there seems to be a broad tendency for income taxes at subordinate levels of government to increase in importance with increasing level of development, although there are some exceptions to this rule.

In some countries, such as Finland and Norway, the income tax threshold in the local tax is much lower than in the central government income tax.

However, schedular mechanisms such as withholding or minimum contributions may be widely used under a global system for ease of administration.

This particular feature may increase the revenue elasticity of the subcentral tax compared with a normal flat rate system to the extent that subcentral governments will share the gains of any bracket creep effects in the federal tax.

This disregards the problems posed by mail order systems, particularly with regard to the control and setting of tax rates (in the United States, some of these problems have been addressed by applying the rates of the destination states to mail order sales). Although based on a fairly limited sample of countries, Table 3 seems to indicate that the degree of development is also important in this regard, in that there is a tendency for sales taxes to be of larger revenue importance for local governments in developing than in developed countries.

Which means that the tax is levied by the jurisdiction in which consumption takes place, independent of the origin of the goods (that is, expotts are exempt and imports are liable to tax), as opposed to the origin principle, according to which the VAT is levied by the jurisdiction in which production takes place, that is, interstate exports are taxed and imports are not.

In China and Russia, ail import VAT accrues to the federal government, and only domestic VAT revenues are shared with the regions.

Formally, the 25 percent local rate is a maximum, but the large majority of regions are believed to apply the maximum rate.

In the majority of countries, provision of regional or local government services is related to the residency of individuals.

Bird , Richard M. , 1993 , “Tax Reform in India,” Economic and Political Weekly , Vol. 28 ( December 11 ), pp. 2721 – 26 .

  • Search Google Scholar
  • Export Citation

King , David N. , 1984 , Fiscal Tiers: The Economics of Multi-Level Government ( London : Allen & Unwin ).

King , David N. , 1992 , ed. , Local Government Economics in Theory and Practice ( London : Routledge ).

McLure , Charles E. , Jr. , 1977 , “The ‘New View’ of the Property Tax: A Caveat,” National Tax Journal , Vol. 30 , No. 1 , pp. 69 – 75 .

Musgrave , Robert A. , and Peggy B. Musgrave , 1980 , Public Finance in Theory and Practice ( New York : McGraw-Hill ).

Oates , Wallace E. , 1972 , Fiscal Federalism ( New York : Harcourt Brace Jovanovich ).

Tanzi , Vito , 1996 , “Fiscal Federalism and Decentralization: A Review of Some Efficiency and Macroeconomic Aspects,” in Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, 1995 ( Washington : World Bank ).

Within Same Series

  • 4 Tax Reform in Russia
  • PART I Theory
  • 6 Recent Tax Policy Trends and Issues in Latin America
  • VII: Tax Reform and IMF Tax Policy Advice
  • Chapter 2. Modernizing the Tax Policy Regime
  • PART III Practice: Developing Countries
  • PART IV Practice: Economies in Transition
  • Chapter 3. Strengthening Tax Administration
  • IV: Income and Wealth Taxes
  • PART II Practice: Industrial Countries

Other IMF Content

  • Revenue Assignments—Tax Policy and Administration
  • 11 Basic Issues of Decentralization and Tax Assignment
  • Rethinking Subnational Taxes: A New Look At Tax Assignment
  • 5 Tax Administration
  • 8 The Assignment of Oil Tax Revenue
  • 12 Local Taxation in an International Perspective
  • Tax Policy Options for a United Germany
  • Technical Assistanceon Tax Policy: A Review
  • How to Design Tax Policy in Fragile States

Other Publishers Content

Asian development bank.

  • A Comparative Analysis of Tax Administration in Asia and the Pacific: Sixth Edition
  • A Comprehensive Assessment of Tax Capacity in Southeast Asia
  • Taxation and Social Protection
  • Mobilizing Taxes for Development
  • Tax Incentives and Investment
  • Reforming the Personal Income Tax System in the People's Republic of China
  • A Comparative Analysis of Tax Administration in Asia and the Pacific
  • Tax Expenditure Estimation Tool Kit
  • The Governance Brief Issue 30, 2017-Localizing Global Agendas in Multilevel Governance Systems: The Benefi ts of Functional Assignment as Core Element of Decentralization Reforms
  • Asian Development Outlook (ADO) 2022: Mobilizing Taxes for Development

Inter-American Development Bank

  • Switching from Payroll Taxes to Corporate Income Taxes
  • The Impact of the Business Cycle on Elasticities of Tax Revenue in Latin America
  • The Harmonization of Indirect Taxes in the Andean Community
  • Quo Vadis Income Tax?: Towards the PIT-CA
  • Economic Integration and the Transformation of the Tax Mix: Cyprus 1990-2001
  • Brazil's ICMS Tax: Origin, Changes, Current Situation, and Paths to Recovery
  • Trade Liberalization and Trade Taxes
  • Party System Institutionalization and Reliance on Personal Income Tax in Developing Countries
  • A Basic Framework for Evaluating Value Added Tax Expenditures

The World Bank

  • Determinants of Property Tax Revenue: Lessons from Empirical Analysis
  • Exploring Reform Options in Functional Assignment
  • Ghana Tax Gap Analysis
  • The Entry of Randomized Assignment into the Social Sciences
  • A Handbook for Tax Simplification
  • Not(ch) Your Average Tax System: Corporate Taxation under Weak Enforcement
  • Academic Peer Effects with Different Group Assignment Policies: Residential Tracking versus Random Assignment
  • Guinea - Opportunities for Enhanced Domestic Revenue Mobilization: Value-Added Tax and Excise Taxes
  • Informality, Consumption Taxes and Redistribution
  • Property Tax Diagnostic Manual
  • Share on facebook Share on linkedin Share on twitter

Cover Fiscal Federalism in Theory and Practice

Table of Contents

International Monetary Fund Copyright © 2010-2021. All Rights Reserved.

tax assignment conclusion

  • [185.194.105.172]
  • 185.194.105.172

Character limit 500 /500

IMAGES

  1. TAX Assignment Fringe Benefits

    tax assignment conclusion

  2. Taxation Assignment

    tax assignment conclusion

  3. Tax assignment Section 13(1)(e) Compensation for Loss of Employment

    tax assignment conclusion

  4. Final Copy of Taxation Assignment

    tax assignment conclusion

  5. Taxation Assignment

    tax assignment conclusion

  6. Tax assignment in bsa

    tax assignment conclusion

VIDEO

  1. Assignment Taxation 1 (ACC2613)

  2. How to Write Introductions & Conclusions in IELTS Task 2

  3. Income tax assignment ( court case part 2)Role play

  4. TAX 2 ASSIGNMENT (ACC 3723)

  5. Income tax assignment (court case part 1)Role play

  6. CA

COMMENTS

  1. Accounting for Income Tax: A Student Research Project

    For each account, the students conducted research on the applicable U.S. tax rules and consulted Topic 740 to determine the applicable GAAP rules. The instructor met with the students and discussed the nature of the assignment, as well as the sequence of research steps.

  2. Navigating Complex Taxation Law Assignments: Your Ultimate ...

    Conclusion. In conclusion, navigating complex taxation law assignments requires a combination of fundamental knowledge, research skills, and effective writing.

  3. How to Write a Conclusion for Research Papers (with Examples)

    The conclusion in a research paper is the final section, where you need to summarize your research, presenting the key findings and insights derived from your study. Check out this article on how to write a conclusion for a research paper, with examples.

  4. COMMUNICATING YOUR TAX RESEARCH - Get Assignment Help Here

    The conclusions should be simply statedtypically only one sentence. Avoid adding or restating your analysis in the conclusion. If you have multiple issues, the conclusions should be numbered to correspond with the issues.

  5. How To Conclude Your US Taxation Assignment Effectively

    US Taxation Assignment Help: How To End Your Assignment with A Bang! A good conclusion is as effective as a good introduction. Just like with other assignments, when writing your US taxation paper, it is important that you end with a great finish.

  6. Expenditure and Revenue Assignment: Principles | SpringerLink

    Foremost among the problems with the conventional view of tax assignment is its failure to recognize the importance of the link between expenditure decisions and tax decisions; that is, the benefit model of subnational, and especially local, government finance.

  7. Tax Planning Assignment 2 - ACT 330 – Introduction to ...

    Assuming Summit’s tax rate is 21% in all years and that it uses a discount rate of 9% in its tax planning decisions, decide whether Summit should elect out of using the installment method for recognizing the gain on this sale.

  8. Expert Tips for Effective Taxation Assignment Writing

    Conclusion: For your taxation assignment to be of the highest caliber, you must first develop a thorough plan. You can improve the clarity, coherence, and general quality of your writing by comprehending the assignment requirements, doing extensive research, organizing your thoughts, and using a logical structure.

  9. How To Write A Taxation Assignment

    Concluding the Research on the Taxation Assignment. A conclusion brings your assignment to closure. Write a conclusion that will summarize the most important points and combines them together into one thread.

  10. 3 Tax Assignment in: Fiscal Federalism in Theory and Practice

    The term “tax assignment” here describes the level of government responsible for determining the level and rate structure of various taxes, whether their revenue is to be collected or received by that level, or shared with others.